A Dilemma of Self-interest vs. Ethical Responsibilities in Political Insider Trading (2024)

As a library, NLM provides access to scientific literature. Inclusion in an NLM database does not imply endorsem*nt of, or agreement with, the contents by NLM or the National Institutes of Health.
Learn more: PMC Disclaimer | PMC Copyright Notice

A Dilemma of Self-interest vs. Ethical Responsibilities in Political Insider Trading (1)

Link to Publisher's site

J Bus Ethics. 2022 Oct 14 : 1–31.

doi:10.1007/s10551-022-05265-0 [Epub ahead of print]

PMCID: PMC9560883

PMID: 36259070

Author information Article notes Copyright and License information PMC Disclaimer

Abstract

Political insider trading has brought substantial attention to ethical considerations in the academic literature. While the Stop Trading on Congressional Knowledge (STOCK) Act prohibits members of Congress and their staff from leveraging non-public information to make investment decisions, political insider trading still prevails. We discuss political ethics and social contract theory to re-engage the debate on whether political insider trading is unethical and raises the issues of conflict of interest and social distrust. Empirically, using a novel measure of information risk, we find that senator trades are associated with substantially high levels of information asymmetry. Moreover, based on inside political information, senators earn significant market-adjusted returns (4.9% over 3months). Thus, our results do not support the prediction made by social contract theory and thereby provide a potential resolution to the ongoing debate on banning stock trading for members of Congress.

Keywords: Politician’s insider trading, STOCK Act, Social contract theory

Introduction

Concerns about politicians’ insider trading are not new.1 Scandals relating to members of Congress using their offices for private financial gains date back to at least 1968 and have plagued both political parties (Barbabella et al., 2009). However, the evidence from the literature on politicians’ investment performance is mixed and provides a range of diverse views on whether or when a politician acts on inside information.2

In April of 2012, the United States Congress passed the Stop Trading on Congressional Knowledge Act (STOCK Act) which made it clear for the first time that the laws against insider trading also apply to members of Congress and their staff members (Belmont et al., 2020). The STOCK Act prohibits members of Congress and their staff from exploiting non-public information “derived from such person’s position” or “gained from the performance of such person’s official responsibilities” as a means for financial gain (Mesiya, 2021). The STOCK Act also requires members of Congress, the President, Vice President, and all Cabinet members to report any trades exceeding $1000 within 45days of the transaction. However, there have been many publicized instances where the STOCK Act’s mandates may have been compromised. For example, between early February and early April of 2020, during the height of the COVID-19 pandemic, twelve senators made 227 stock purchases worth as much as $98 million, and the thirty-seven members of the House made 1358 trades worth as much as $60 million (Fandos, 2020; Mesiya, 2021). Furthermore, not a single member of Congress has been prosecuted under the STOCK Act since its passage almost a decade ago, suggesting certain ineffectiveness and even failures of the STOCK Act (Fandos, 2020; Mesiya, 2021). Nevertheless, it is not our primary goal to assess whether the STOCK Act is an ultimate failure or success.

The main purpose of this paper is two-fold. First, we aim to re-visit the issue of political insider trading by developing a sound ethical framework that integrates political ethics (also known as political morality, the practice of making moral judgments about political action by political agents) and social contract theory. Political ethics not only forbid political leaders to do things that would be inappropriate in private life but also require them to meet higher ethical standards than would be necessary for private life. For example, they may have less of a right to privacy than ordinary citizens and no right to use their office or connections for personal financial benefit. Ultimately, at the core of concern here are issues arising from “conflict of interest.”3 Politicians’ insider trading can be a harbinger of conflict of interest as it can create distrust between shareholders and between the firm and its shareholders. In addition, considering politicians’ fiduciary duty to the general public (Blau et al., 2021), politicians’ insider trading may signal the existence of the conflict of interest between themselves, the firms, and other stakeholders. Social contract theory was given its first full exposition by Hobbes (1651) and is associated with modern moral and political theory (Locke, 2003; Rousseau, 1987). Social contract theory views politicians’ ethical or moral obligations as emanating from a societal agreement to form a society where all stakeholders live in harmony. Social contract theory suggests that ethical political insiders should not violate any of the following four moral propositions, i.e., fairness, harmlessness, honoring property rights, and fiduciary relationships. Thus, according to social contract theory, trading by politicians or regulators on non-public information per se should not be considered unethical based on various moral arguments unless such trading raises concerns associated with conflict of interest.

Second, we aim to use the lenses of political ethics and social contract theory to interpret the results of an empirical analysis of financial market dynamics surrounding the electronic stock transactions of U.S. Senators. Specifically, we investigate the performance of stocks purchased by senators and the amount of informed trading occurring around their trades using a novel information asymmetry measure recently developed by Yang et al. (2020). Our results show that senator trades generally beat the S&P 500 over different intervals ranging from 1week to 3months following the trade. Additionally, and most importantly, our tests reveal that periods around senator trades are characterized by high levels of information asymmetry, consistent with the notion that senators’ connections with access to knowledge on legislative or lobbying activity may drive such informed transactions. These findings call into question the ethics of insider trading by U.S. senators.

Politicians’ preferences for stocks could be motivated by the engagement in quid pro quo relations with firms (Tahoun, 2014), and therefore their asset holdings may reflect latent corporate connections.4 Furthermore, while trading by members of Congress or their staff was not exempt from the federal securities laws (including the insider trading prohibitions) prior to the STOCK Act, there were distinct legal and factual issues that could arise in any investigations or prosecutions of such cases.5 The STOCK Act was intended to minimize potential conflicts of interest among politicians, firms, and investors, increase transparency, and combat insider trading by preventing politicians from benefiting based on market-moving information ahead of general investors. However, as discussed in Levinthal (2021), many members of Congress did not fully comply with the STOCK law as recently as 2021, prompting ethics overseers to push for banning lawmakers and politicians from trading individual stocks. Furthermore, the passage of the STOCK Act did not stop the practice of sharing political information with firms impacted by such information but also with financial intermediaries.6 Such practice is legal because it allows politicians to solicit feedback from relevant parties on prospective legislation (Kim, 2013b). An unintended consequence (and the subject of recent debate) is the potential transfer of private political information to individuals who can profit from it without having to disclose it publicly. Indeed, there is recent empirical (Gao & Huang, 2016) and anecdotal evidence7 that valuable political information gets transmitted in the market, supporting the notion that a political intelligence industry plays an important informational role.

Although the STOCK Act prohibits non-public information for profit in the first place, political insider trading keeps evolving as financial markets, financial technology, and the associated laws keep changing (Aktas et al., 2008; Blau et al., 2021; Kim, 2013a, 2013b, 2013c; Moore, 1990; Ziolkowski, 2020) indicating the difficulty in finding consensus among business ethicists, financial economists, and policy-makers. In contrast to social contract theory’s dimensions of fairness and level-field information access to all market participants (Klaw & Mayer, 2021; Salbu, 1995), we postulate that political insider trading by the Senate is associated with conflict of interest and can therefore increase social distrust.

Consistent with the view that senators’ purchases are often driven by superior information, our results show that stocks purchased by senators outperform the market over the 3months following the date of the trade.8 Their abnormal return that exceeds the return of the S&P 500 index is about 4.9% over the 3-month period. Moreover, we show that periods around senator trades’ dates are associated with high levels of information asymmetry (AIV). This implies that many more people are trading around these dates, likely on the same congressional knowledge. Interestingly, AIV around senators’ stock transactions is significantly greater than AIV around earnings announcement days. The degree of information asymmetry around senator stock purchase dates is also associated with the senator’s personal characteristics (including age, tenure, and committee membership) and the legislative activity of both the senator and the Congress overall. Many of the same factors also explain the buy-and-hold market-adjusted returns of stocks purchased by senators. The evidence clearly shows that politically informed trading manifests itself in stock prices. In addition, our findings suggest that politicians’ transactions reveal latent and politically informed trades by others who do not have to file. Thus, the results of informed trading we document should be viewed as a lower bound of the extent of political insider trading in the U.S. Senate. In addition, the evidence of elevated levels of information asymmetry around politician trades is consistent with the notion that there is greater potential for conflict of interest. Therefore, our combined evidence does not support the social contract theory.

Our study is distinct from Blau et al. (2021), who examined liquidity and volatility during the post-amendment period of the STOCK Act. It is also different from Belmont et al. (2020). They focused on the potential underperformance of the stock trading by the U.S. senators without dealing with the ethical dimensions of politicians’ trades and the associated information asymmetry aspect. Instead, we regard political insider trading from the perspective of the social contract theory to contemplate the ethical debate related to the conflict of interest and social distrust. Furthermore, our novel empirical approach allows us to capture the extent of information asymmetry surrounding senator stock trades, thereby providing insight into the magnitude of sensitive political information transfer that could lead to the conflict of interest that undermines social trust.

This paper makes several contributions to the literature. First, our findings do not support the prediction made by the social contract theory and suggest that politicians’ insider trading raises the issue of a conflict of interest among market participants that could increase social distrust. This calls for greater scrutiny of politicians’ trades and an expansion of the set of political actors required to file their stock trades. Second, we provide novel evidence of political insider trading and a new method to detect it. Prior literature focuses on analyzing senator portfolios and excess returns (e.g., Eggers & Hainmueller, 2014; Ziobrowski et al., 2004). Third, our paper contributes to the literature on price-based measures of information risk (e.g., Yang et al., 2020) and firms’ exposure to political risk (e.g., Hassan et al., 2019) by showing that politicians’ trades can reveal undocumented levels of information asymmetry. To the best of our knowledge, this paper is the first to introduce abnormal idiosyncratic volatility (AIV) as a measure of the degree of information asymmetry among investors in the analysis of politicians’ trades.

This paper is structured as follows: We briefly review the literature on political ethics, social contract theory, virtue ethics, and political insider trading and develop hypotheses. The following section describes the methodology used and specifies empirical versions of hypotheses. In the subsequent section, we describe the data collection process and report summary statistics. We report our results and associated robustness checks in the following section. Finally, we conclude in the last section.

Related Literature and Hypothesis Development

Political Ethics, Social Contract Theory, and Virtue Ethics

From an ethics perspective, it is widely documented that most forms of insider trading are unethical because it generates profits at other parties’ expense by exploiting information advantages gained through means of position or association (i.e., connections) instead of through public channels (Bhattacharya & Daouk, 2002; Christensen et al., 2017; Gao & Huang, 2016; Jerke, 2010). Indeed, some studies suggest that the buying or selling of securities by insiders with access to non-public information is unethical, unfair, or even illegal (Blau et al., 2021; Brudney, 1979; Klaw & Mayer, 2021; Werhane, 1989, 1991). In contrast, others (e.g., see Manne (1966), Gilson and Kraakman (1984), Meulbroek (1992), Lin and Rozeff (1995), and Bainbridge (2006), among many others) question whether insider trading is economically harmful or advance amoral arguments concerning its impact on the informativeness of prices. Therefore, it is crucial to re-engage in the debate about whether profiting by exploiting political information is unethical. For this task, the political ethics literature allows us to enjoin aspects of ethical expectations derived under social contracting theory with certain aspects of virtue ethics.

Under the STOCK Act, politicians have a disqualifying conflict of interest in a political decision if it is foreseeable that the decision will directly impact their private finances. A conflict of interest arises when the private interests of a politician or official clash with that of the public. The key ethical question is whether private interest could influence, or appear to influence, the voting decisions officials make in their working lives. Henceforth, public officials should not take unfair advantage of their position by using non-public information that could benefit them at the expense of others.

Social contract theory suggests thatall stakeholders should live together in society following an agreement/contract that establishes moral and political rules of behavior. For example, if politicians live according to a social contract (Hobbes, 1651; Locke, 2003; Rousseau, 1987), they can live morally by their own choice. Social contracts can be explicit, such as laws, or implicit, such as raising one’s hand in class to ask questions. The U.S. Constitution is often mentioned as an explicit example of part of America’s social contract. It sets out what the government can and cannot do. People who choose to live in America agree to be governed by the moral and political obligations outlined in the Constitution’s social contract. Indeed, whether social contracts are explicit or implicit, they provide a valuable framework for harmony in society. Political ethics requires politicians’ trades to meet higher ethical standards than would be necessary for the personal standard of pursuing financial profit, mainly due to potential conflict of interest concerns (Blau et al., 2021; Jensen & Meckling, 1976; Rawls, 1971; Stark, 2003). Such conflicts of interest can undermine trust (Blau et al., 2021) and make the public lose faith in the integrity of governmental decision-making processes, leading to perceptions of corruption, lack of accountability, and social distrust.

As discussed above, inconsistencies between personal (or private) and political morality in political ethics can be viewed as a “conflict of interest.” However, it is essential to recognize that these two concepts of morality can also maintain a typical positive relationship. Someone who learned the skills necessary in the political sector may apply these qualities in a setting outside of politics, often viewed as a private setting. In contrast, someone entering the political ground may already have the qualities and virtues expected in a professional environment. Reciprocity, as in the context of deriving those traits, is commonly present when entering the field if one did not already learn the qualities. Although both concepts of morality include different expectations, there is a correlation between the two. Whether the virtues and values were acquired or previously held, they factor in and apply to both settings. Those who have emerged into the intense political domain should understand that virtues and morals can influence each other (Mendeluk, 2018). We assert that building one’s character by viewing political morality above private morality can be substantially more ethical when we contemplate the issue of politicians’ insider trading.

Salbu (1995) analyzes the expansive and constricted approaches of insider trading regulation within a framework of basic tenets of the American capitalist social contract regarding the legitimacy of property claims. The insider trading law has progressed from an expansive approach under which corporate outsiders, including politicians, are permitted to trade on non-public information provided such trading does not breach a fiduciary duty. Salbu (1995) further claims that the existing constricted approach to the regulation of insider trading is deficient in meeting the expectations of two core components of the social contract. It discourages procedural equality of opportunity and endorses claims to property not characterized by legitimate methods of acquisition or transfer. Because the old, expansive regulatory interpretation was more consistent with the terms of the social contract concerning property claims, it served our economic and ethical expectations more effectively than the current system. Accordingly, Salbu (1995) suggests that the expansive approach to regulating insider trading be reestablished under United States law.

We apply social contract theory to consider whether it provides a sound ethical foundation for prohibiting trading on material non-public information. Social contract theory shares the premise that whether a practice is “ethical” or “unethical” depends upon whether those governed by such rules have consented or would consent (Dunfee & Donaldson, 1995). We contend that stock trading based on material non-public information by politicians would not be an ideal or even an ethical practice to which most investors would agree because it runs directly counter to the traditional concept of the ethics of fairness (Klaw & Mayer, 2021; Salbu, 1995; Zingales, 2012).

Based on Salbu (1995), Fandos (2020), and Mesiya (2021) further argue that the STOCK Act is an inappropriate and ineffective legal mechanism for remedying issues of political ethics. As a result, concerning political insiders, we consider that an ethical approach might be better than the legal approach to dealing with financial conflicts of interest. In addition, Jerke (2010) advocates for public disclosure of political intelligence-gathering activities by outside actors, such as lobbyists and hedge funds. Jerke (2010) further contends against prohibiting trading on political intelligence by external actors because these actors are merely the Washington equivalents of security analysts, whose information-gathering functions are legitimate, if not desirable. However, unlike Jerke (2010), we maintain that political insider trading is unethical to the extent that it generates profits at other parties’ expense by exploiting information advantages gained through political position or connection (Bhattacharya & Daouk, 2002; Christensen et al., 2017; Gao & Huang, 2016). It is unethical mainly due to conflict of interest even if politicians pass through the hurdle of the legitimacy of property claims.

One competing alternative to the social contract theory related to politicians’ insider trading is the theory of virtue ethics. Virtue ethics emphasize the “right” way to be is that, which stimulates the development of personal characteristics to attain the “good” or “honesty” (Aristotle, 1926; Klaw & Mayer, 2021; Maclntyre, 1984, 1988; Murphy, 1999). For example, Aristotle (1926) proposed nine critical virtues: wisdom, prudence, justice, fortitude, courage, liberality, magnificence, benevolence, and temperance. While Aristotle’s list of virtues does not contain “creating efficiencies” in the financial market, virtue theory can broaden insider trading ethics even if insider trading were legal.

We consider that politicians who trade on material non-public information would need to reconcile their behavior with the virtue of “honesty.” It is crucial to address whether political insider traders are honest. It would be hard to imagine that they are without disclosure to the financial markets and all the market participants. However, political insider traders are unlikely to be honest to all stakeholders because they neither need to take full responsibility for their trading actions nor treat other stakeholders fairly.

While virtue theory is a plausible alternative to social contract theory regarding politicians’ insider trading, we consider social contract theory as more relevant to politicians’ insider trading than virtue theory. That is primarily because virtue theory is mute on price efficiency in financial markets. Thus, the theory of virtue ethics does not precisely predict abnormal financial returns or information asymmetry related to politicians’ insider trading other than the possible existence of the politicians’ dishonesty that could create distrust between shareholders (Blau et al., 2021).

Political realists (Korab-Karpowicz, 2010) criticize that ethics has no place in politics. They claim that moral rules should not bind politicians if they are effective in the political sphere. They further claim that politicians should put more emphasis on the national interest. However, Walzer (1977) points out that if realists are asked to justify their claims, they will almost always appeal to their moral principles. Another criticism comes from those who argue that one should not pay so much attention to politicians and policies but instead look more closely at the larger structures of society where the most severe ethical problems lie (Barry, 2005). However, we maintain that while one should not ignore structural injustice, too much emphasis on structural injustice issues could potentially lead us to neglect both the practice of information exploitation for private benefits and the issues arising from conflict of interest. We further contend that the current practices of politicians’ insider trading are creating social distrust among market participants.

Politicians and Insider Information Trading

Early evidence of potential conflict of interest consistent with political insider trading is provided by Boller and Ward (1995). They show that out of a random sample of 111 members of Congress and Senate, 25% of members’ stock transactions were directly linked with legislative activity. After that, several studies attempted to quantify the performance of politicians’ stock investments and to answer whether they make abnormal profits, but the results were mixed. Ziobrowski et al. (2004) show that between 1993 and 1998, senators’ stock trades outperform the market by approximately 10% per year. Yet, Eggers and Hainmueller (2014) show that between 2004 and 2008, Congress members’ trades underperform the market by, on average, 2–3% annually. Perhaps, pre-STOCK Act data can generate conflicting results depending on the period of the analysis because “it is also possible that members simply stopped reporting their incriminating transactions once they realized that academics and the media were watching them” (Kim, 2013c, p. 170).

Huang and Xuan (2019) show that in the year following the establishment of the STOCK Act, there were no surprise mergers or earnings announcements that politicians took advantage of, and theysuggest that the STOCK Act might have stopped politicians’ insider information trading. Yet, given the plethora of anecdotal evidence in 2020 alone and the fact that many senators need to file corrections every year, it is still unclear whether the STOCK Act has effectively increased transparency and reduced insider trading. Blau et al. (2021) empirically examine the sample of stocks held by members of Congress compared to control stocks and find that liquidity significantly worsens, and stock volatility substantially increases during the post-STOCK Act amendment period. They conclude that restrictions on non-corporate insider trading are associated with unfairness and harmfulness.

Hypothesis Formation

Social contract theory provides a sound ethical foundation for prohibiting insider trading in the U.S. (Klaw & Mayer, 2021; Salbu, 1995). As Salbu (1995) notes, insider trading profits generally render the transaction unfair because a trader with inside information does not deserve the gains she receives by utilizing that information. Given the opportunity, market participants would generally refuse to agree to a system that permits insider trading (Tramontano, 2017; Zingales, 2012) because earned merit has little to do with rewarding those who trade with the unearned advantage of inside information. We posit that the same ethical problem applies to politicians, as trading on inside political information may create unearned benefits.9

We also maintain that political insider trading by the Senate has the potential to disrupt fair equality of opportunity. We postulate that political insider trading can pose potential conflicts of interest among firms, shareholders, politicians, and financial intermediaries. The breach of the fair equality of opportunity increases social distrust and raises the potential for conflict of interest among stakeholders, thereby adversely affecting financial efficiencies. However, gauging the true extent of political insider information trading is not easy. Kim (2013b) points out that the STOCK Act is not binding for all legislators.10 Thus, the trading activity of senators (and potentially House members) should be viewed as a subset or as a proxy for all others who have access to the same information but do not file their transactions (Kim, 2013b). As a result, there is a potential for politicians who have access to material non-public information to disseminate it in violation of some of social contract theory’s four ethical propositions (i.e., fairness, harmlessness, honoring property rights, and fiduciary relationships). Second, to the extent that the four ethical principles are adhered to, it should not be possible for politicians to generate high abnormal profits simply because they access insider information. For example, abnormal returns could be possible when investing in industries that fall under the jurisdictions of their committees (Karadas, 2018) or even without a committee link when investing in local firms (Eggers & Hainmueller, 2014) because in these cases, politicians may be in a better position to exploit public information.

Nevertheless, Kocieniewski and Farrell (2020) document that members of Congress with oversight of industries such as financial services, defense contracting, and health care earned huge gains recently through well-timed trades in the market. Given their advantages in terms of oversights of such industries, local firms, and timing, it is questionable whether the system should allow substantial financial gains to politicians. Moreover, most current literature on government insiders fails to consider differences in financial know-how between corporate and government insiders. The latter, e.g., a legislator, can use her inside information to make an informed trade. Still, alack of skill might prevent her from making abnormal returns achieved by a financial analyst trading on the same information, as Ferguson and Voth (2008) showed.

Social contract theory assumes that whether a practice is right or wrong depends upon whether those governed by such rules have consented or would consent (Dunfee & Donaldson, 1995). Thus, we would argue that high financial gains by politicians should not be a practice most people would agree with because it runs counter to traditional capitalist concepts of the moral equality of opportunity and associating moral desert with merit (Blau et al., 2021; Salbu, 1995; Zingales, 2012).

Initially, we contemplate whether the Senate’s inside trading could generate a positive financial gain. One can expect politicians’ trading to be free of systematic use of legislative and political information after the STOCK Act’s enactment. Belmont et al. (2020) analyze the buy-and-hold abnormal returns of politicians between March 2012 and 2020, and they confirm the previous results of Eggers and Hainmueller (2014) by showing that the actual returns of politicians outperform the market returns but fail to outperform the industry-size benchmark. Their results support the premise that senators possess valuable legislative information while lacking company-related inside information.11

To the extent that the social contract theory is valid, we speculate that politicians’ investments should not generate high abnormal returns.

H1

The average stock returns following politicians’ trades do not outperform the market returns.

We also examine whether stock returns following politicians’ trades exceed industry returns (Corollary 1). Any finding of senator stocks outperforming the market but not the industry could imply that (a) information acquired from their legislative activities helps choose the suitable industries to invest in, and (b) senators lack the skills and/or additional company-type information to select the best stocks within industries.

Additionally, the fact that the senators are not outperforming industry portfolios does not necessarily mean that others with access to the same information as these politicians (e.g., their staff members or other (state) legislators) are not doing so. Therefore, one must be careful when claiming that politicians and their aids do not make abnormal returns using their informational advantage. It is also essential to note that only a small number of political insiders report their transactions. Furthermore, it might be worth noting that not outperforming the industry portfolio does not necessarily mean they are not informed. Politicians can consistently beat the market and make abnormal returns by picking the right industry. Therefore, an analysis of abnormal returns cannot easily lead to solid conclusions about whether the politicians’ trades are informed or not. By examining not only abnormal returns but also by introducing a more sophisticated method based on a price-based measure of information risk (i.e., the AIV of Yang et al., 2020), our approach allows us to gauge the extent of trading stemming from legislative and political inside information and reveal its most relevant factors and possible channels.

Following Kim (2013b), we aim to test to what extent the trading activity of senators could serve as a proxy for the trading of all other politicians who possess the same information but are not required to file their transactions. In this case, periods of the senators’ trades should be associated with a high level of information-driven trading or information asymmetry.

Our approach allows us to examine whether politicians (i.e., senators) belong to the “first wave of informed traders.” This is plausible because their work puts them in a position to be the first to receive value-relevant news (Kim, 2013c), i.e., they may be directly informed because they are aware that their legislative activities would cause future stock price changes. Therefore, to the extent that the social contract theory is valid, we expect political insider trading with more information-driven transactions will not happen. We further construct our corollary hypothesis to examine whether politicians are in the first wave of informed traders. Thus, we postulate the following:

H2

Politicians’ stock trades do not occur in periods of higher probability of information-driven trading.

Our subsequent interest is whether informed trading by senators is associated with their tenure, membership on essential committees, and other personal characteristics used in previous research (e.g., Ziobrowski et al., 2004). Moreover, since the spouses and children of senators also have to disclose their trades, we can observe if senators try to mask their insider trades by giving information to their family members or potentially by trading in their name. This expands on Karadas (2018), who shows that politicians’ spouses outperformed the market before the STOCK Act. Additionally, as Eggers and Hainmueller (2014) show, there is a possibility that a senator might receive corporate insider information from firms’ lobbying efforts related to legislation before their committees. Henceforth, we expect that the involvement of lobbyists and the level of activity in Congress can also influence the extent of informed trading. Accordingly, we anticipate the following:

H3

If political insider trading exists, its extent is related to politicians’ characteristics, the account (self or family member) used to trade, and relevant lobbying and legislative activity around the transaction date.

Methodology

Concept of Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility (AIV)

Yang et al. (2020) show that their price-based measure of information risk, AIV, relates to insider trading,12 institutional trading activities, and short selling. There is a positive relationship between the AIV and the size of informed return run-ups before the earnings announcements, suggesting that some traders are informed about the earnings before the public. Our approach is inspired by their suggestion that the AIV measure of information risk “may also be applied to other information events such as mergers and acquisitions, product recalls, and patent applications” (Yang et al., 2020, p. 530). We modify their measure to compare the volatility surrounding the stock transaction dates of politicians to that during the rest of the year. This modification is made because, unlike quarterly earnings, where the start of the information event is clearly defined, politicians’ trades are not necessarily the start of the event. As in Yang et al. (2020), the idiosyncratic volatility is measured on the three-factor model of Fama and French (1993).

Ri,t=αi+βiMKTt+siSMBt+hIHMLt+i,t,

1

where Ri,t is the daily excess return on the stock i at time t, MKT is the value-weighted market portfolio excess return over the risk-free rate, SMB is the size factor, and HML is the value factor.

To compute abnormal idiosyncratic volatility (AIV), we need to specify the time windows for the calculations. Following Ali and Hirshleifer (2017) and Yang et al. (2020), we define the 5-day window (t − 2, t + 2) surrounding the politician’s stock trade event (t) to minimize possible noise. For every transaction, we create two sub-periods. First, the around-the-trade (ATT) period includes the 5days in the transaction window. Second, the non-around-trade (NAT) period is the whole year period before the trade, excluding the ATT days. To compute the AIV, we run the Fama–French three-factor regression for each stock using the previous year’s daily data. We obtain an estimated daily residual i and then compute the annualized idiosyncratic volatility of stock separately for the ATT and NAT using the following formulae:

IVATT=ln252×jATTj2nATT-1

2a

IVNAT=ln252×jNATj2nNAT-1,

2b

where ln stands for the natural logarithm and nATT (nNAT) is the number of days in the around-the-trade (non-around-trade) period. Finally, we define the abnormal idiosyncratic volatility (AIV) as the difference between the volatility around the trade (ATT) and the rest of the year (NAT):

Note that the AIV is calculated for each stock and trade separately. This approach allows us to estimate information asymmetry associated with the transaction (i.e., the extent of political insider trading). In contrast with the previously used return analyses of politicians’ trades, the AIV-based approach captures unusual stock price patterns around their trades. Using the AIVs around the dates of politicians’ stock trades, we can detect informed trading activity by people who do not disclose their trading activity but still have access to the same information.13

Testing Buy-and-Hold Portfolios of Political Insiders

Several papers have attempted to estimate the investment returns of politicians. For example, Ziobrowski et al. (2004) use a technique known as calendar-time transaction-based analysis (Odean, 1999). They create portfolios by purchasing stocks on the same day as the politicians, which will be then sold 12months later. These synthetic portfolios built from politicians’ transactions outperform a passive market index by 12% per year in the Senate (1993–1998) and 6% in the House (1985–2001). However, Eggers and Hainmueller (2013) criticize their findings. Since Congress members do not hold these synthetic portfolios, the actual returns that members earned with their portfolios can be substantially different from expected returns. In addition, they note that results from such synthetic portfolios can be susceptible, and their returns can vary significantly across other specifications. Using the data before the STOCK Act, Eggers and Hainmueller (2013) show no significant outperformance of politicians.

To test Hypothesis 1 and Corollary 1 by avoiding the criticism associated with a technique that leads to the aforementioned, divergent conclusions we compute buy-and-hold market-adjusted and industry-adjusted returns over several holding periods. We follow each politician’s stock trade using information from electronic reports of senators during the January 2012–December 2019 period. For several periods of a buy-and-hold strategy, we define the buy-and-hold abnormal return on a politician’s investment as

BHARt,pimkt=t=1top1+ri,t-t=1top1+rmkt,t

4a

BHARt,piind=t=1top1+ri,t-t=1top1+rind,t,

4b

where ri,t is the daily return on firm i at time t. rmkt,t and rind,t are the daily returns of S&P500 and industry, respectively. The Fama–French (1997) 48 industry classification is used to define an industry. For the period p, we consider 1w, 2w, 1m, 2m, and 3m, representing periods of 1week, 2two weeks, 1month, 2months, and 3months, respectively. We acknowledge that our empirical tests are not free from the criticism of Eggers and Hainmueller (2013). Then, the empirical version of H1 on whether or not a politician’s investment outperforms the market is

H10:BHARt,pimkt0. Alternatively, H1A:BHARt,pimkt>0.

The empirical version of Corollary 1 for whether or not a politician’s investment exceeds the industry portfolio returns is

C10:BHARt,piind0. Alternatively, C1A:BHARt,piind>0.

Based on H1 and C1, we expect four different scenarios: (1) outperforming the market and industry portfolios, (2) outperforming the market portfolio and underperforming the industry portfolio, (3) underperforming the market portfolio and outperforming the industry portfolio, and (4) underperforming the market and industry portfolios.

Note that calculating actual returns is almost impossible for two reasons. First, politicians can choose whether it is a partial sale or a complete sale when politicians report their transactions, but there are no clear definitions. Moreover, matching buys with the corresponding sales is nearly impossible because they must report ranges of total dollars invested instead of exact dollar amounts. Second, many politicians dilute their transactions, i.e., they split their purchases and sales into several smaller transactions rather than reporting one significant transaction. Hence, it is difficult to calculate the actual returns precisely, and more significant transactions could be noisy.14

Testing Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility

To test H2 and H3, we employ the information risk measure of AIV with the modifications described earlier. In H2, we investigate whether the probability of informed trading (i.e., AIV) is higher during periods surrounding dates with stock transactions by senators.

H2a0:AIV0. Alternatively, H2aA:AIV>0.

As Yang et al. (2020) mention, the calculated AIV might be lower than in reality because there may be several potential events during the other period (NAT) where information asymmetry plays a role (e.g., quarterly earnings, mergers and acquisitions, product recalls, etc.).

Next, we examine whether politicians are in the first group of insiders. One can conjecture that senators are informed, but it is unclear whether they are generally among the first group of people trading on the information. To test this, we modify the computation of the AIV described earlier by shifting the five-day event window. We define AIVF (i.e., politicians trade first), where the five-day window includes the transaction day and the following 4days. Similarly, we define AIVL (i.e., politicians trade last) as 4days before the transaction and the transaction day. If politicians’ trades are genuinely in the “first wave” of informed trades, the 5-day window following their trade will contain most of the informed trades. Thus, AIVF is expected to be greater than AIV. Conversely, if their trades are lagging behind those of other informed traders about a certain, AIVL will present a larger value than AIV.

H2b10:AIVFAIV. Alternatively, H2b1A:AIVF>AIV.

H2b20:AIVLAIV. Alternatively, H2b2A:AIVL>AIV.

Data and Descriptive Statistics

We use data from the United States Senate Financial disclosures (https://efdsearch.senate.gov/), which started in 2012 following the STOCK Act. Senators have an option to either (1) report their transactions on a paper form that is then scanned and made available online or (2) fill it out electronically (See Fig. Fig.A1A1 as an example of the electronic reports). They have 30–45days to report each transaction and generally do this in batches rather than individually.15

A Dilemma of Self-interest vs. Ethical Responsibilities in Political Insider Trading (3)

Example of period transaction report

From the electronically filed reports, we can identify the type of investment, whether the asset was bought or sold, whose account was used for the trade, the range of dollar value of the transaction, and the security. The final dataset contains 8064 total transactions, with 7092 stocks, 67 non-public stocks, 13 stock options, 319 municipal securities, 288 corporate bonds, and 285 other securities (See Table Table1).1). The electronic version of the reports covers the transactions of 49 different senators, 22 Democrats, and 27 Republicans. The average tenure is 11.5years, and 47% of these senators were members of the House previously. As part of the STOCK Act, records are only kept for 6years after retirement. Therefore, no transaction records are available for the senators who retired many years ago. Accordingly, we mostly skip or interpret results for 2012 and 2013 with caution because of the meager number of observations (5 in 2012 and 19 in 2013).16

Table 1

Distribution of senators’ trades by security type and year

Panel A: Total number of trades
Type of transaction/securityDirection of tradeYear of the recorded transaction
20122013201420152016201720182019Total
StockBuy254247526317237453233605
Sale014758214815816974313487
Corporate bondBuy01342327163236169
Sale00352711141517119
Municipal securityBuy171433293227114257
Sale246510227662
Non-public stockBuy0035888739
Sale00141116528
Stock optionBuy000042006
Sale002120027
Other securitiesBuy0013934407511182
Sale01710123529103
TotalBuy3134888227338218874914258
Sale265268685066517774703806
All519101416901239147216649618064
Panel B: Senators’ trades by security type: percentage distribution by year (row percentages)
Type of transaction/securityDirection of tradeYear of the recorded transaction
20122013201420152016201720182019Total (100%)
StockBuy0.1%0.1%11.8%20.9%17.5%20.1%20.7%9.0%3605
Sale0.0%0.0%13.6%23.5%13.8%16.7%20.0%12.4%3487
Corporate bondBuy0.0%0.6%20.1%13.6%16.0%9.5%18.9%21.3%169
Sale0.0%0.0%29.4%22.7%9.2%11.8%12.6%14.3%119
Municipal securityBuy0.4%2.7%5.4%12.8%11.3%12.5%10.5%44.4%257
Sale3.2%6.5%9.7%8.1%16.1%35.5%11.3%9.7%62
Non-public stockBuy0.0%0.0%7.7%12.8%20.5%20.5%20.5%17.9%39
Sale0.0%0.0%3.6%14.3%3.6%39.3%21.4%17.9%28
Stock optionBuy0.0%0.0%0.0%0.0%66.7%33.3%0.0%0.0%6
Sale0.0%0.0%28.6%14.3%28.6%0.0%0.0%28.6%7
Other securitiesBuy0.0%0.0%7.1%4.9%18.7%22.0%41.2%6.0%182
Sale0.0%1.0%6.8%9.7%1.0%22.3%50.5%8.7%103
TotalBuy0.1%0.3%11.5%19.3%17.2%19.3%20.8%11.5%4258
Sale0.1%0.2%13.8%22.8%13.3%17.1%20.4%12.3%3806

Panel A reports the total amounts of transactions by year and security type, with the last column and row reporting the total by security type and year, respectively. In contrast, Panel B reports the distribution of each security and direction of trade by year (row percentages). The last column contains the total number of transactions over the entire period and represents a hundred percent base for scaling

Table Table11 depicts the distribution pattern of transactions by type of security and direction of the trade over the years, where Panel A shows the total number of trades and Panel B shows the percentage of the total transaction for the given type of security and direction of the trades. Again, we observe that there are very few observations in 2012 and 2013.

The number of transactions is not very stable through the years. The dip in transactions in 2016 could be the uncertainty about the presidential election and the power shift in the political landscape. A similar reason may apply to the drop in 2019 when rising uncertainty led more traders to adjust their portfolios toward less risky assets. This is supported by the evidence in Panel B of Table Table1,1, where we observe the highest percentages of purchases of municipal (44.4%) and corporate bonds (21.3%) during the sample period.17 Since many analysts were predicting a stock market crash and recession in 2019, senators might have become more conservative in their investments.

Additionally, it is plausible that senators may have been reluctant to take advantage of some specific economic situations such as recessions because they might trigger greater public scrutiny. This is a reasonable explanation based on a recent incident. Prior to the COVID-19 lockdowns, the senate committees on health and foreign relations had a meeting where they were informed on how the COVID-19 outbreak would affect the country and financial markets. Following the meeting, they made many transactions to sell their stocks, leading to an investigation by the ethics committee (Ziolkowski, 2020).

As part of the STOCK Act, even senators’ immediate family members need to report their transactions following the same format. The internet appendix (Table 12) reports the distribution of senators’ trades by security types. Our findings show that most transactions happen on joint accounts, followed by spousal accounts, self-accounts, and child accounts. This result supports Karadas’ (2018) findings, which suggest that senators’ spouses might trade based on insider information. While this may indeed be the case, it could also indicate that politicians may use their spouses’ accounts to conduct some of their trades, hoping to keep a low profile, as the spouses’ trading history may not be followed as closely as their own.

Next, we compare diluted versus non-diluted transactions. For a transaction to be classified as diluted, either a senator has made several transactions involving the given security on the same day, or she has traded the same security in immediately subsequent trading days. We observe that 45% of transactions were diluted. On the one hand, this pattern could be consistent with politicians’ use of the noise caused by uninformed traders to make a profit on their insider information without alerting the market, which is in line with the model of Kyle (1985). Or politicians’ desire to mask total investment size makes it hard for observers to calculate actual returns. On the other hand, this pattern of diluted transactions could reflect senators’ attempt to lower the average cost per share.

We should note that there might be even more diluted transactions than we are catching. For example, there could be transactions that are a day (or more) apart but made with the same intentions in mind. However, extending the possible time window associated with defining diluted transactions raises the chance of increasing the noise in the data. Therefore, we restrict the time window to only consecutive trade days.

The pattern of the diluted trades over the years is unclear. However, their number is likely affected by political uncertainty and pushed by legislative activity, which provides a foundation for inside political information. For example, election years are characterized by more diluted trades than non-election years. This suggests that the dilution could be correlated with potential insider trading because it serves as a tool to mask the trading activity. We will examine these issues in more detail later.

Empirical Results

Buy-and-Hold Stock Returns Following Senator’s Trades

To examine buy-and-hold excess return (market), we conduct two tests for mean values (t tests) and median values (sign tests). H1 is set to test whether stock returns outperform the market in each given year and for each holding period commencing with the day of a senator’s trade. In Table Table2,2, the first set of rows tests whether the average abnormal return is different from zero, while the second set of rows contains the sign tests (also known as the median tests).

Table 2

Excess return (market) for different holding periods

Hold periodStatistical testYear of the recorded transactionOverall
201420152016201720182019
One weekMean0.008***0.004*0.0030.001 − 0.010***0.0050.001
(t test)(3.815)(1.839)(1.367)(0.503)(− 4.699)(1.600)(0.992)
Sign test1.350***1.322***1.283***1.243***0.690***1.1711.129***
[p-value][0.004][0.000][0.002][0.005][0.000][0.000][0.209]
Two weeksMean0.007*** − 0.005*0.018***0.009*** − 0.0050.013***0.005***
(t test)(2.674)(− 1.685)(5.242)(4.706)(− 1.501)(3.094)(3.95)
Sign test1.379***0.9681.760***1.385***1.0231.733***1.276***
[p-value][0.002][0.685][0.000][0.000][0.791][0.000][0.000]
One monthMean0.017*** − 0.015***0.048***0.022*** − 0.015***0.029***0.011***
(t test)(3.733)(− 3.220)(11.909)(7.214)(− 3.582)(5.032)(6.106)
Sign test1.755***0.9372.412***1.692***0.763***2.082***1.358***
[p-value][0.000][0.397][0.000][0.000][0.000][0.000][0.000]
Two monthsMean0.037*** − 0.03***0.095***0.037*** − 0.0090.047***0.024***
(t test)(6.271)(− 5.088)(20.215)(9.165)(− 1.501)(5.834)(9.845)
Sign test1.796***0.765***3.852***1.838***0.9472.471***1.490***
[p-value][0.000][0.000][0.000][0.000][0.495][0.000][0.000]
Three monthsMean0.051***0.0050.121***0.056***0.013*0.077***0.049***
(t test)(7.212)(0.865)(21.974)(11.458)(1.873)(7.921)(18.226)
Sign test2.040***1.258***5.273***2.081***1.339***2.149***1.929***
[p-value][0.000][0.002][0.000][0.000][0.000][0.000][0.000]
Number of observations3837366216816972113336

This table reports excess return (market) following senators’ stock trades for five different holding periods from 1week to 3months. Excess return (market) is defined as the difference between stock return and S&P500 index return. For each hold period, the first set of rows tests whether the average abnormal return is different from zero, while the second set of rows contains the results of the sign tests (also known as the median tests). For the sign test statistics, the ratio of positive/negative returns is reported along with statistical significance. The first 2years (2012 and 2013) are omitted due to very few observations

***, **, and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively

Overall, Table Table22 results reject the first null hypothesis (H10) and support H1A, which states that politicians’ buy-and-hold returns outperform the market. Except for the shortest holding period, we find evidence that senators’ stock purchases outperform the market at the 1% significance. The average buy-and-hold abnormal return (market) is about 0.5% for two weeks and increases to 4.9% for 3months.

When we analyze the patterns of the excess market returns by year, we still observe that the averages are positive and significant at a 1% level in most cases. However, a few negative and significant excess returns are present for some holding periods in 2015 and 2018. We also note that in both 2015 and 2018, the largest portion of stocks was sold, and most transactions were diluted.18 In addition, we examine excess returns using a different benchmark such as CRSP value-weighted market index and find that the results remain the same.

Overall, the observed patterns of the abnormal market returns are amplified with the more extended hold periods. This longevity suggests that value-relevant political information may take a while to become incorporated into stock prices. Moreover, a non-parametric version of our test procedure, the sign test of Snedecor and Cochran (1989), confirms and magnifies the results of the t tests. Thus, the combined results do not support the prediction based on the social contract theory.

We examine industry-adjusted returns for stock purchases and report the results in Table Table3.3. The mean excess returns are not significantly different from zero for a large portion of the results. The lack of significance for the t test could be explained by the high variation of the excess returns (industry). On average, outperforming the industry portfolio would be less common than outperforming the market since corporate insider information is primarily available only to a limited number of senators who, for example, may sit on essential committees and observe corporate lobbying activities (Eggers & Hainmueller, 2014). Thus, the results of industry-adjusted returns are not conclusive.

Table 3

Excess return (industry) for different holding periods

Hold periodStatistical testYear of the recorded transactionOverall
201420152016201720182019
One weekMean0.0010.001 − 0.002 − 0.002 − 0.004*** − 0.001 − 0.002**
(t test)(0.625)(0.414)(− 1.238)(− 1.622)(− 3.039)(− 0.513)(− 2.349)
Sign test1.1520.9291.0361.0450.831**1.0140.98
[p value][0.184][0.337][0.688][0.591][0.016][0.952][0.583]
Two weeksMean − 0.001 − 0.0010.005** − 0.002 − 0.006***0.000 − 0.001
(t test)(− 0.218)(− 0.221)(2.070)(− 1.443)(− 2.917)(− 0.003)(− 0.901)
Sign test0.9640.9091.164*1.0640.840**1.0600.99
[p-value][0.759][0.209][0.065][0.443][0.025][0.674][0.680]
One monthMean − 0.0040.0050.011*** − 0.004* − 0.013*** − 0.004 − 0.002
(t test)(− 1.087)(1.400)(3.462)(− 1.712)(− 4.960)(− 1.037)(− 1.109)
Sign test0.8771.1621.179**0.860*0.628***1.0080.93**
[p-value][0.220][0.460][0.045][0.060][0.000][0.998][0.029]
Two monthsMean0.0000.0020.01*** − 0.005 − 0.015*** − 0.011* − 0.003
(t test)(− 0.033)(0.4220)(3.086)(− 1.278)(− 4.521)(− 1.908)(− 1.647)
Sign test1.0931.0301.242***0.9710.745***0.9030.98
[p-value][0.414][0.712][0.008][0.729][0.000][0.474][0.6532]
Three monthsMean − 0.0030.017***0.004 − 0.009** − 0.011*** − 0.001 − 0.001
(t test)(− 0.399)(3.777)(0.994)(− 2.051)(− 2.879)(− 0.104)(− 0.18)
Sign test0.9441.327***0.9170.794***0.823**0.9540.95
[p-value][0.609][0.000][0.296][0.003][0.012][0.783][0.150]
Number of observations3837336216786912113317

This table reports excess return (industry) following senators’ stock trades for five different holding periods from 1week to 3months. Excess return (industry) is defined as the difference between stock return and industry return, where industries are defined by the Fama–French 48 industry classification. For each hold period, the first set of rows tests whether the average abnormal return is different from zero, while the second set of rows contains the results of the sign tests (also known as the median tests). For the sign test statistics, the ratio of positive/negative returns is reported along with statistical significance. The first 2years (2012 and 2013) are omitted due to very few observations

***, **, and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively

Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility

This section aims to analyze if politicians’ trades are associated with periods of higher information asymmetry. Since such information asymmetry cannot be simply attributed to a few recorded politicians’ transactions, high AIV values during periods around politicians’ trades would imply that either many more people at Capitol Hill are relying on the inside political information or this valuable inside information could be leaked to other market participants. Accordingly, we test H2 by the decomposition of factors that drive abnormal idiosyncratic volatility (AIV).

Table Table44 below contains mean AIVs based on a 5-day window around the stock trade across years and different types of characteristics. For the sake of space, we report only the 5-day results, but the complete set of results using alternative windows is available upon request. We find that information asymmetry associated with stock trades by senators is considerably high. It is, on average, 3.6%, which is higher than the average AIV of 1.1% related to quarterly earnings announcements in Yang et al. (2020). Thus, our results on the AIV do not support the social contract theory prediction of H2. Table Table44 presents the average value of the AIV computed across years, personal characteristics, and account types. The highest AIV is associated with the joint accounts (9.7%), followed by spouse-owned accounts (−1.8%), and self-owned accounts (−3.0%), with the child accounts representing a very low (large negative) value of the AIV (−12.5%). These results suggest that politicians may refrain from using their self-owned accounts when trading based on potential insider information. A child’s account is also limited, unlike corporate insider trading found in Berkman et al. (2014). Berkman et al. (2014) find that the guardians behind under-aged accounts successfully pick stocks. Moreover, they show that the guardians tend to channel their best trades through children’s accounts.

Table 4

The mean of the abnormal idiosyncratic volatility (AIV)

CharacteristicsYear of the recorded transactionTotal mean
201420152016201720182019
Child − 14.5% − 7.6% − 6.8% − 32.9%11.3% − 5.9% − 12.5%
Joint − 8.7%9.2%21.2%1.2%14.2%4.6%9.7%
Self − 12.9% − 0.5% − 4.1% − 10.7%9.5%4.6% − 3.0%
Spouse − 12.9%1.6%6.1% − 7.3%7.2% − 5.2% − 1.8%
Purchase − 19.5%9.7%6.9% − 7.4%12.3%7.6%2.9%
Sale (Full) − 9.7% − 2.1%4.4% − 7.8%5.4% − 3.0% − 2.9%
Sale (Partial) − 0.2%8.6%29.1%7.5%10.3%0.7%10.3%
Age 41–50 − 36.5%0.2%20.1% − 16.2% − 35.9%20.4% − 18.9%
Age 51–60 − 9.1% − 3.5%2.4% − 7.9% − 4.6% − 13.1% − 5.0%
Age 61–65 − 13.0% − 18.1%2.9% − 10.4%4.0%5.7% − 3.3%
Age > 65 − 17.6%11.5%18.2% − 2.6%15.6%2.3%8.3%
Non-diluted transactions − 11.6% − 0.1%8.6% − 3.4%11.6%3.6%1.9%
Diluted transactions − 12.9%10.2%15.0% − 6.0%9.5%0.7%5.1%
Year mean − 12.4%6.8%12.6% − 4.3%10.4%2.7%3.6%
Number of observations84215001075123713526966710

This table reports the mean Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility (AIV) computed over the 5-day window for different subsamples based on account type, transaction type, age group, diluted transactions, and by year. AIV corresponds to the standard definition of the AIV associated with the politicians’ transactions, i.e., using Eqs.(1)–(4), which excludes 5days around the senators’ transactions. (i.e., 2days before, trading day and 2days after the transaction). A transaction is categorized as diluted if multiple transactions occur by the same senator for the same stock on the same day or on subsequent days. The first 2years (2012 and 2013) are omitted due to very few observations

Regarding the direction of trade, we observe that partial sales are associated with a higher AIV even when compared to purchases. This could, however, be caused by the lack of legislative activity in 2014, when the mean AIV for purchases was low (and negative). Moreover, senators can use their insider information to minimize losses. For example, in early 2020, senators with access to information about the incoming measures against COVID-19 took their money out of the market (Ziolkowski, 2020).

The effect of diluted transactions could be more complex because of a wider window and a higher noise associated with diluted dealings. The results are very similar when we use other windows (e.g., 7 days) for the calculation of AIV19 but with lower mean values, suggesting that increasing the time window prevents us from capturing more information asymmetry and raises the noise in the measurement.

One potential problem with interpreting an increase in the AIV around politicians’ trades as evidence of political insider trading could be related to other major corporate announcements on dividends, earnings, mergers and acquisitions, and stock repurchases. These events may convey no important political information but lead to high AIV. We examine the frequencies of trades made during the major firm-specific announcements to verify if this is the case. Thus, we want to compare how the information asymmetry during the senator stock transaction period to that around quarterly earnings announcements.

In Table Table5,5, we report that these events, on average, represent only around 4.2% of the overall senators’ trades. Moreover, we conduct an additional test after removing the transactions that occur during the events and find that our results are similar to those obtained from the whole sample, presented in the following sections.20

Table 5

Overlaps of senators’ trading period with the other non-political information events

Information eventsYearTotal
201420152016201720182019
Quarterly earnings announcements213542174512172
Dividend announcements91018525471
Mergers and acquisition announcements3723103450
Stock repurchases announcements0000202
Total number of transactions related to all events335283327520295
Total number of transactions89915731112130414427547084
% of transactions related to all events3.67%3.31%7.46%2.45%5.20%2.65%4.16%
% of transactions related to earnings announcements2.34%2.23%3.78%1.30%3.12%1.59%2.43%

The table contains the frequencies and percentages of transactions that are made during the major corporate announcements. We collect the announcements of dividends and quarterly earnings from Compustat. The announcements of merger and acquisitions and stock repurchases are extracted from SDC

Alternative Measures of Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility

In this section, we define modified versions of the AIV to analyze if politicians are in the first wave of informed traders and to compare the extent of the AIV associated with the politician’s trade with the AIV connected with the quarterly earnings, as defined by Yang et al. (2020). First, we calculate AIV around the quarterly earnings for every year and thestock for which a senator transaction occurred. We denote this abnormal idiosyncratic volatility as AIVE (earnings) to differentiate it from other calculated measures. To test H2(b1) and H2(b2), we define AIVF (first informed) and AIVL (last informed) using different event windows.

Given the fact that while AIV, a price-based measure of informed trading, in the context of Yang et al. (2020), is measured surrounding a widely announced corporate event (i.e., earnings report), there is a caveat concerning the AIV measured around a very quiet (non-public) senator trade as a proxy of information asymmetry. Market microstructure literature has introduced several quantity-based measures of asymmetric information, the most prominent of which is the Easley et al. (1996) measure of Probability of Informed Trading (PIN) and the closely related VPIN measure of Easley et al. (2012). Although these measures have also been criticized in the literature,21 they could allow us to test the robustness of our findings using the quantity-based measures of informed trading. Unfortunately, we lack access to the high-frequency trading data necessary to construct the PIN (or VPIN) measure. Instead, we construct three alternative proxies for information asymmetry, which have been used in prior literature (e.g., Brennan & Subrahmanyam, 1996; Armstrong et al., 2011; Yang et al., 2020). Spread is computed as (asking price–bidding price)/traded price, multiplied by the number of trades. Abnormal volume is computed as in Yang et al. (2020). We compare trading volume (in millions) in the 5-day window surrounding the politician’s trade to trading volume in the rest of the year as we did for AIV. Abnormal turnover is the difference in turnover (= trading volume/shares outstanding) between the 5-day window and the rest of the year. We observe that these proxies are highly correlated with AIV.

In Table Table6,6, we show the means of the AIV, AIVF, and AIVL along with AIVE throughout the years. The highest AIV is associated with the regular definition of the AIV, followed by AIVL and then by AIVF. This evidence suggests that senators are in the middle of the pack of informed traders and rarely the first or the last to trade on the news, negating H2(b1) and H2(b2).

Table 6

The mean of different measures of the AIV by year

Variables201420152016201720182019Total mean
Alternative AIV measures
AIV − 12.30%***7.10%***12.70%*** − 4.10%***10.10%***3.50%*3.70%***
AIVF − 14.30%***1.60%9.00%*** − 8.10%***6.00%*** − 2.20% − 0.50%
AIVL − 6.50%***7.10%***7.60%*** − 5.30%***5.90%***2.90%2.60%***
AIVE − 1.30% − 3.30%***4.00%*** − 4.00%***1.00% − 2.10%** − 0.90%**
Alternative information asymmetry measures
Spread15.57***19.78***29.03***17.24***26.84***20.13***21.89***
Abnormal volume0.97***1.22***2.80***0.98***1.48***1.66***1.5***
Abnormal turnover1.22*2.50***1.501.24***1.97***2.04***1.79***
Observations84115211082123213526936728

This table compares the mean of different measures of Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility (AIV) and alternative information asymmetry measures. For AIVF, the event window includes the trading day and four following days. For AIVL, the event window includes the trading day and four preceding days. AIVE is computed around the firm’s announcement of earnings, following the methodology of Yang et al. (2020). Spread is computed as (asking price–bidding price)/traded price, which is multiplied by the number of trades. Abnormal volume is trading volume (in millions) in the 5-day window surrounding the politician’s trade minus trading volume in the rest of the year. Abnormal turnover is the difference in turnover (= trading volume/shares outstanding) between the 5-day window and the rest of the year. The first 2years (2012 and 2013) are omitted due to very few observations.

***, **, and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively.

The observed differences across years could partly be due to different levels of legislative activity or changes in the ruling party/administration. For example, the lowest level of legislative activity is found in 2014, implying the least amount of potential political inside information available to senators. This explains the negative mean values of the AIV in 2014. In 2017, the first year of the Trump administration, information that could affect the market might have been driven mainly by the president himself, potentially leading to the observed negative values for AIV.

To formally test H2(b), we use both the t test and the sign test, as in the previous section. We report the battery of tests in Table Table7,7, documenting the differences between the average values of various AIVs. It confirms that the regular AIV has the highest values. We also observe that the AIV associated with politicians’ trades is higher than that around earnings announcements (AIVE as defined in Yang et al., 2020). This result implies that, on average, information asymmetry is greater during periods around senator transactions than during periods around quarterly earnings announcements. More importantly, this result supports our view that there is a flow of valuable private information from Capitol Hill and that senators’ trading activity is only the tip of the iceberg. Most individuals who have access to the information do not have to report their investments. We also find that three alternative variables present similar patterns. Similar to AIV measures, the average values are relatively higher in 2015, 2016, and 2018 and lower in 2014 and 2017.

Table 7

Differences between various AIV measures

Difference in AIVStatistical testYear of the recorded transactionOverall
201420152016201720182019
AIV – AIVFMean0.0180.056***0.040***0.040***0.046***0.067***0.045***
(t test)(1.248)(6.035)(4.101)(4.181)(5.646)(4.939)(10.656)
Sign test1.210***1.0221.172***1.144***1.106**1.168**1.125***
[p-value][0.006][0.699][0.010][0.020][0.068][0.045][0.000]
AIV − AIVLMean − 0.058***0.0010.050***0.0130.042***0.0060.012***
(t test)(− 4.052)(0.034)(4.125)(1.352)(5.373)(0.464)(2.892)
Sign test0.774***1.0690.9841.146***1.250***1.353***1.086***
[p-value][0.000][0.201][0.809][0.017][0.000][0.000][0.000]
AIVF − AIVLMean − 0.076*** − 0.057***0.006 − 0.028** − 0.002 − 0.062*** − 0.034***
(t test)(− 3.817)(− 4.569)(0.372)(− 2.079)(− 0.144)(− 3.305)(− 5.541)
Sign test0.684***0.877***0.786***0.846***1.096**0.8860.868***
[p-value][0.000][0.012][0.000][0.004][0.097][0.120][0.000]
AIV − AIVEMean − 0.111***0.105***0.091*** − 0.0040.109***0.053**0.051***
(t test)(− 5.343)(7.196)(3.673)(− 0.230)(7.614)(2.566)(6.769)
Sign test0.684***1.474***0.9420.9181.349***1.211***1.096***
[p-value][0.000][0.000][0.3601][0.156][0.000][0.018][0.000]
Number of observations84215001075123713526966710

This table shows the results of different measures of Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility (AIV), computed over the 5-day window. For AIVF, the event window includes the trading day and four following days. For AIVL,the event window includes the trading day and four preceding days. AIVE is computed around the firm’s announcement of earnings, following the methodology of Yang et al. (2020). For each hold period, the first set of rows tests whether the average abnormal return is different from zero, while the second set of rows contains the results of the sign tests (also known as the median tests). For the sign test statistics, the ratio of positive/negative returns is reported along with statistical significance. The first 2years (2012 and 2013) are omitted due to very few observations.

***, **, and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively.

Determinants of Political Information Risk and Politicians’ Stock Performance

We now estimate the regression models of political information risk (AIV) and politicians’ stock trade performance (buy-and-hold returns). Again, our stock performance analysis does not extend over periods longer than 3months as in other tests. Both models include an extensive list of standard control variables. Still, our focus is on political variables (i.e., politicians’ personal and legislative characteristics) that may reveal possible channels for the information asymmetry around senators’ stock transaction dates.

Several variables are related to Senate legislative activity. The Legislative effectiveness score (LES)22 measures how well the senator advances her agenda items through the legislative process and into law. A high LES score implies that the senator has greater influence and better connections within the U.S. Senate (Fowler, 2006a, 2006b) and is better informed. Senators can also gather information by serving on various committees. With better access to important news (e.g., on the policy agenda in general or specific pieces of legislation) and with the benefit of observing relevant individual firm lobbying, committee service can give them further valuable insight (Eggers & Hainmueller, 2014). To capture this effect, we include five committees based on the power ranking defined by Stewart (2012): Finance, Appropriations, Rules and Administration, Armed Services, and Foreign Relations. We include the Number of bills lobbied for (reported in hundreds) and the Number of lobbyists on the day of the transaction (reported in thousands) to explain the importance of the current legislative events. For every transaction date, we sum the number of introduced bills that have at least one lobbyist.

Additionally, we sum the total amount of lobbyists across all bills introduced on the transaction date. Finally, there is some evidence that investments in local firms could result in higher returns (Eggers & Hainmueller, 2014). We, therefore, include the Home bias indicator variable equal to 1 when a senator’s stock trade involves a firm from their home state and 0 otherwise. We also add two industry-related variables. Industry concentration is the value of the Herfindahl index that is computed by each firm’s total stock value within the same industry. The weight of each stock in the given industry based on stock value is included.

As firm controls, we employed standard variables used in asset pricing models: Past profitability, Illiquidity, Firm size, Book-to-market ratio, and Beta. Past profitability is measured using four separate past stock returns, following Brennan et al. (2012). Similarly, we use a group of variables Rm-1,Rm-3,m-2,Rm-6,m-4,Rm-12,m-6, which stand for returns over the last month, previous months 3–2, previous months 6–4, and previous months 12–6, respectively. Illiquidity is measured following Amihud (2002) as a sum of absolute values of daily returns divided by daily volume for the year, multiplied by 10^6. Firm size is the log of the market value of equity. The book-to-market ratio is the log of the book-to-market ratio. Beta is calculated using the Fama–French (1993) three-factor model over the past 6months. However, Beta is only used as a control variable for the AIV regression. We provide detailed descriptions (Table 11) and summary statistics (Table 14) in the internet appendix.

In Table Table8,8, we report results for three AIV regression specifications. Column (1) contains both tenure and age variables. In column (2), we omit the tenure and keep the age variables. This alternative specification serves as a sensitivity check since tenure and age are highly correlated. Finally, in column (3), we use a subsample that includes only stock purchases. Table Table88 reveals some interesting results. First, senator tenure and age are the only personal characteristics that remain statistically significant when we include the other control variables. Specifically, early-career and mid-career senators’ trades generate significantly higher informed trading than late-career senators. More specifically, in column (1), senators with shorter tenure (0–4years) present an 11.8 percentage points higher AIV, on average, than senators with longer tenure (14–35years).

Table 8

Regression of AIV

Dependent variable = AIV
(1)(2)(3)
All transactionsAll transactionsStock purchases
Senator tenurea
Tenure 0–40.118***0.094**
(0.032)(0.041)
Tenure 5–130.0820.105*
(0.050)(0.062)
Age categoryb
Age 41–50 − 0.279*** − 0.196** − 0.146*
(0.085)(0.079)(0.082)
Age 51–60 − 0.129*** − 0.041 − 0.135**
(0.040)(0.031)(0.058)
Age 60–65 − 0.094*** − 0.039 − 0.061
(0.033)(0.028)(0.046)
Account typec
Child − 0.056 − 0.052 − 0.086
(0.043)(0.043)(0.054)
Joint0.0450.082***0.081**
(0.029)(0.026)(0.040)
Spouse − 0.0160.0000.006
(0.035)(0.032)(0.043)
Other characteristics
Female − 0.004 − 0.022 − 0.068
(0.039)(0.036)(0.061)
Diluted − 0.011 − 0.008 − 0.027
(0.014)(0.014)(0.018)
Home bias − 0.173*** − 0.163*** − 0.175***
(0.032)(0.032)(0.040)
Legislative variables
Legislative effectiveness score (LES)0.0280.020 − 0.001
(0.021)(0.020)(0.028)
Finance Committee0.102**0.061*0.141**
(0.041)(0.035)(0.067)
Appropriations Committee0.008 − 0.0180.085**
(0.032)(0.030)(0.040)
Rules and Administration Committee − 0.0120.018 − 0.027
(0.026)(0.025)(0.037)
Armed Services Committee − 0.024 − 0.005 − 0.053
(0.045)(0.033)(0.070)
Foreign Relations Committee − 0.0400.027 − 0.093
(0.049)(0.041)(0.076)
Number of bills0.090**0.080**0.101**
(0.041)(0.041)(0.049)
Number of lobbyists − 0.031*** − 0.030*** − 0.044***
(0.010)(0.010)(0.012)
Industry-related variables
Industry concentration1.575***1.570***1.042***
(0.274)(0.273)(0.389)
Weight of stock in the industry − 0.041 − 0.0340.037
(0.105)(0.104)(0.160)
Constant0.0970.179 − 0.277
(0.207)(0.197)(0.272)
Firm control variablesYesYesYes
Industry and year fixed effectsYesYesYes
R-squared0.12070.11800.1697
Observation (N)528352832793

Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility (AIV) computed over the 5-day event window. Firm control variables include Size (log(market value of equity)), Book to Market, Illiquidity, past profitability, and market beta (12months). Reported are robust standard errors in parentheses

ais for senator tenure, where the base category is Tenure 14–35

bis for the age group, where the base category is Age > 65

cis for the account type, where the base category is Self

***, **, and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively

The Number of bills coefficient is positive and significant at the 5% level, suggesting that higher levels of overall legislative activity generate more insider information, increasing information asymmetry. The coefficient of Finance Committee (the most powerful committee based on the ranking in Stewart (2012)) is also positive and significant. This indicates that trades by the finance committee members are significantly more informative than the rest, suggesting that such a committee might be privy to a substantial amount of value-relevant information.

The negative Home bias effect may appear surprising at first glance. However, this effect may imply that senators may be reluctant to widely share insider information about firms in their home state. As mentioned previously, the AIV captures the abnormal stock activity resulting in departures from the Fama–French asset pricing model. Therefore, changes in AIV cannot merely be caused by a few reported trades but rather require substantial additional trading activity. Hence, we would not detect information asymmetry when inside information is available to a limited number of market participants. Alternatively, the negative coefficient of Home bias may indicate that senators deliberately avoid trading on insider information about home state firms.

We see that the Number of lobbyists has a negative and significant effect on AIV, which is consistent with the view that lobbyists reduce information risk by disseminating value-relevant information to the market. In sum, information risk around senator stock trade dates appears to increase with the senatorial activity (Number of bills) and decrease with lobbying activity (Number of lobbyists). Thus, overall, we have some supporting but mixed evidence of H3.

Industry concentration is positively related to AIV. The estimated coefficient is consistently significant across three models at the 1% level. We interpret this as evidence that, if a few large firms dominate the industry, there are a number of small-sized firms that tend to present high levels of information asymmetry.

Note that stocks with many politicians’ trades over the past year would have fewer NAT days by construction. This feature could potentially distort the value of AIV and hence consequently affect the results. To account for this data-specific aspect and test our results’ robustness, we also run a weighted OLS regression, using the ratio of NAT days to ATT days as weights. The results are similar to those in the main specification, showing that our results are not biased by a larger number of ATT days. The detailed results are not presented here; they are available in the internet appendix (Table 15).

Now, we will analyze the abnormal market returns to determine the main drivers of individual profitability for the other stock purchases. Table Table99 Panel A depicts the market-adjusted buy-and-hold returns analysis results for the five different periods over 3months. Interestingly, stocks bought by early- or mid-career senators have higher market-adjusted returns over longer holding periods. Contrary to the AIV regressions, age is a positive and significant predictor of future returns. These results can suggest that older senators’ trades are associated with more information asymmetry, but the younger senators are making more profitable investments.

Table 9

Regression of buy-and-hold abnormal return (BHAR)

Panel A: Regression of BHAR (market)
Dependent variable = BHAR (market)
Period for buy-and-hold
1week2weeks1month2months3months
Senator tenurea
Tenure 0–4 − 0.021*** − 0.032*** − 0.016*0.0190.034***
(0.005)(0.007)(0.009)(0.012)(0.013)
Tenure 5–13 − 0.016** − 0.023** − 0.0190.0010.010
(0.007)(0.010)(0.014)(0.018)(0.020)
Age categoryb
Age 41–500.0300.0290.0170.004 − 0.050
(0.051)(0.071)(0.101)(0.131)(0.142)
Age 51–600.035***0.047***0.049*** − 0.005 − 0.029
(0.007)(0.010)(0.014)(0.018)(0.019)
Age 60–650.027***0.0090.0180.002 − 0.007
(0.006)(0.008)(0.011)(0.014)(0.015)
Account typec
Child0.0000.002 − 0.0040.0010.000
(0.006)(0.009)(0.012)(0.016)(0.017)
Joint0.0060.017***0.0110.0020.008
(0.004)(0.006)(0.008)(0.011)(0.012)
Spouse − 0.0020.0080.0050.0150.015
(0.005)(0.007)(0.010)(0.012)(0.014)
Other characteristics
Female0.0020.024*** − 0.002 − 0.037** − 0.053***
(0.007)(0.009)(0.013)(0.017)(0.019)
Diluted − 0.0010.003 − 0.003 − 0.003 − 0.001
(0.002)(0.003)(0.004)(0.005)(0.006)
Home bias0.0020.0100.019*0.044***0.059***
(0.005)(0.008)(0.011)(0.014)(0.015)
Legislative variables
Legislative effectiveness score (LES) − 0.001 − 0.0050.013**0.037***0.032***
(0.003)(0.004)(0.006)(0.008)(0.008)
Finance Committee0.015**0.0050.006 − 0.012 − 0.019
(0.008)(0.011)(0.015)(0.020)(0.021)
Appropriations Committee − 0.010** − 0.026*** − 0.0100.0110.017
(0.004)(0.006)(0.009)(0.011)(0.012)
Rules and Administration Committee0.0070.014**0.024***0.032***0.031***
(0.004)(0.006)(0.008)(0.011)(0.012)
Armed Services Committee0.024***0.0180.015 − 0.027 − 0.041*
(0.008)(0.011)(0.016)(0.020)(0.022)
Foreign Relations Committee0.031***0.037***0.056***0.052** − 0.001
(0.009)(0.012)(0.017)(0.022)(0.024)
Number of bills − 0.011* − 0.027*** − 0.045***0.0100.014
(0.006)(0.008)(0.012)(0.015)(0.016)
Number of lobbyists0.003**0.008***0.015***0.012***0.005
(0.001)(0.002)(0.003)(0.004)(0.004)
Information asymmetry
AIV0.0030.005*0.013*** − 0.005 − 0.008
(0.002)(0.003)(0.004)(0.006)(0.006)
Industry-related variables
Industry concentration0.049 − 0.031 − 0.230** − 0.0450.257**
(0.046)(0.064)(0.091)(0.119)(0.129)
Weight of stock in the industry − 0.011 − 0.029 − 0.017 − 0.011 − 0.111***
(0.015)(0.021)(0.030)(0.039)(0.043)
Constant0.0050.0130.003 − 0.129 − 0.035
(0.042)(0.059)(0.084)(0.109)(0.118)
Firm control variablesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry and year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
R-squared0.07150.08920.13020.20980.2151
Observation (N)28002800279927992799
Panel B: Regression of BHAR (industry)
Dependent variable = BHAR (industry)
Period for buy-and-hold
1week2weeks1month2months3months
Senator tenurea
Tenure 0–4 − 0.006* − 0.010** − 0.0030.0040.017*
(0.003)(0.004)(0.006)(0.008)(0.010)
Tenure 5–13 − 0.000 − 0.0040.0090.0080.000
(0.005)(0.007)(0.009)(0.013)(0.015)
Age categoryb
Age 41–500.0460.0400.0550.029 − 0.011
(0.036)(0.048)(0.069)(0.091)(0.111)
Age 51–600.009*0.0080.011 − 0.004 − 0.028*
(0.005)(0.006)(0.009)(0.012)(0.015)
Age 60–650.008**0.003 − 0.001 − 0.017* − 0.029**
(0.004)(0.005)(0.007)(0.010)(0.012)
Account typec
Child0.001 − 0.0010.0040.021*0.025*
(0.004)(0.006)(0.008)(0.011)(0.013)
Joint0.0030.0040.0010.0040.003
(0.003)(0.004)(0.006)(0.007)(0.009)
Spouse − 0.004 − 0.0020.0020.018**0.014
(0.003)(0.005)(0.007)(0.009)(0.011)
Other characteristics
Female0.009**0.0060.013 − 0.009 − 0.030**
(0.005)(0.006)(0.009)(0.012)(0.014)
Diluted − 0.002 − 0.000 − 0.003 − 0.006 − 0.007
(0.001)(0.002)(0.003)(0.004)(0.005)
Home bias − 0.0000.009*0.013*0.032***0.049***
(0.004)(0.005)(0.007)(0.010)(0.012)
Legislative variables
Legislative effectiveness score (LES) − 0.0000.0030.0020.015***0.022***
(0.002)(0.003)(0.004)(0.005)(0.007)
Finance Committee0.013**0.0010.009 − 0.017 − 0.036**
(0.005)(0.007)(0.010)(0.014)(0.016)
Appropriations Committee0.0040.0000.0050.0080.005
(0.003)(0.004)(0.006)(0.008)(0.010)
Rules and Administration Committee − 0.002 − 0.0000.0010.014*0.018*
(0.003)(0.004)(0.006)(0.008)(0.009)
Armed Services Committee0.007 − 0.0010.005 − 0.011 − 0.028*
(0.005)(0.007)(0.011)(0.014)(0.017)
Foreign Relations Committee0.0080.0100.0140.013 − 0.021
(0.006)(0.008)(0.012)(0.015)(0.019)
Number of bills − 0.002 − 0.010* − 0.020** − 0.0070.008
(0.004)(0.006)(0.008)(0.010)(0.013)
Number of lobbyists0.002**0.003**0.006***0.004* − 0.000
(0.001)(0.001)(0.002)(0.003)(0.003)
Information asymmetry
AIV0.003*0.006***0.008***0.0030.008*
(0.002)(0.002)(0.003)(0.004)(0.005)
Industry-related variables
Industry concentration0.0270.042 − 0.104* − 0.154* − 0.081
(0.032)(0.043)(0.062)(0.082)(0.100)
Weight of stock in the industry − 0.016 − 0.037*** − 0.039*0.017 − 0.054
(0.011)(0.014)(0.021)(0.027)(0.033)
Constant − 0.004 − 0.000 − 0.019 − 0.0280.026
(0.029)(0.040)(0.057)(0.075)(0.092)
Firm control variablesYesYesYesYesYes
Industry and year fixed effectsYesYesYesYesYes
R-squared0.05390.04590.06870.09820.1052
Observation (N)28002800279927992799

The dependent variable is BHAR (market) in Panel A and BHAR (industry) in Panel B. Firm control variables include Size (log(market value of equity)), Book to Market, Illiquidity, past profitability, and market beta (12months). Reported are robust standard errors in parentheses

ais for senator tenure, where the base category is Tenure 14–35

bis for the age group, where the base category is Age > 65

cis for the account type, where the base category is Self

***, **, and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively

The legislative effectiveness score (LES) coefficient is not significant for the short holding period models but turns positive and significant for the more extended period models (≥ 1month). This suggests that senators who are better connected within the legislative network may possess information that takes at least 2months to be incorporated into market prices. Home state stocks bought by senators also perform significantly better over more extended holding periods, which supports the findings of Eggers and Hainmueller (2014). Coupled with the fact that the trades of home state stocks are associated with lower AIV (reported in Table Table8),8), this result implies that senators may not share value-relevant information about home state firms with many others. We find that AIV is a significant and positive predictor of two-week and 1-month returns. Interestingly, this time period is matched with a period of 30–45days for senators to report their transactions.

In addition, we analyze the industry-adjusted returns and report the analysis in Table Table99 Panel B. The results are generally consistent with the market’s abnormal returns. We observe that politicians with a high Legislative effectiveness score (LES) outperform even the industry for longer term periods. Furthermore, we find that both home bias and AIV remain strong predictors of industry-adjusted returns. These results suggest that even though senator trades, on average, do not outperform the industry portfolios, there might be some specific instances where senators will have a superior stock picking ability.

Overall, our buy-and-hold returns analysis nicely complements the findings of AIV regressions. Our results show that senators’ stock trading activity reported in electronic filings is information-driven and that the magnitude of information asymmetry predicts future returns. Nevertheless, the politically informed trading we uncover could be the tip of the iceberg since many more people have access to the same information but do not have to file their trades.23

Sale Transactions

While purchases signal a positive view of the stock, sales trades include a more complex and diverse set of possible motivations. For example, the decision to sell could not only be driven by negative information but more commonly, by liquidity needs or by the decision to secure a profit or minimize a loss. Moreover, the timing of a sale can be distorted by decision bias like the disposition effect.

The STOCK Act does not require senators to report the exact amount invested or the price at which they purchased (and sold) the security, making it impossible to accurately calculate realized returns on their investments. This, in turn, makes it hard to disentangle the different motives for selling thoroughly. As a result, even though there are documented cases of senators’ informed selling to protect their investments (e.g., selling their stocks before the incoming measures against COVID-19), proper identification of such a subsample of sales transactions remains elusive given the current data. Moreover, the analysis of sale transactions needs to be performed separately using different methods. It is because neither buy-and-hold of stocks after senators’ stock sales nor a portfolio analysis after selling by senators (as reported by Eggers & Hainmueller, 2013) can distinguish among sales motivated by insider information, disposition effect, liquidity-based trading, or other motivations.

Table Table1010 provides a robustness test of politicians’ stock trade performance using an alternative measure based on the premise that the average sale should be less informed than the average purchase trade. We match every purchase transaction with the most recent sale transaction by the same politician that occurred within a week of the purchase. We then compute the difference of the market-adjusted returns by subtracting the return of the stock the senator sold from the return of the stock just purchased.24

Table 10

Sale transactions

Hold periodStatistical testYear of the recorded transactionOverall
201420152016201720182019
One weekMean − 0.541**1.298***0.508*0.3281.338***0.190.679***
(t test)(− 2.124)(4.207)(1.661)(1.504)(5.685)(0.52)(5.766)
Sign test0.749**1.348***1.0960.9871.298***1.1271.120***
[p-value][0.014][0.000][0.314][0.927][0.002][0.396][0.003]
Two weeksMean − 1.373***2.823***2.074***0.512*2.604***0.5521.556***
(t test)(− 4.184)(6.447)(4.675)(1.744)(6.498)(0.965)(8.851)
Sign test0.561***1.417***1.320***0.9871.581***0.5791.184***
[p-value][0.000][0.000][0.002][0.927][0.000][0.468][0.000]
One monthMean − 1.722***3.062***5.617***1.131***3.646***0.8572.622***
(t test)(− 2.753)(5.123)(9.248)(2.581)(6.697)(0.988)(10.489)
Sign test0.9871.329***1.719***1.1411.442***0.9821.303***
[p-value][0.954][0.000][0.000][0.167][0.000][0.946][0.000]
Two monthsMean − 2.288***2.846***9.781***1.161*4.671***5.231***3.896***
(t test)(− 2.893)(3.905)(11.776)(1.719)(5.955)(4.171)(11.37)
Sign test0.8771.248***2.306***1.0931.530***1.730***1.395***
[p-value][0.276][0.009][0.000][0.357][0.000][0.000][0.000]
Three monthsMean − 3.917***5.303***11.642***1.738**8.773***8.499***5.84***
(t test)(− 3.917)(6.804)(13.251)(2.045)(8.966)(4.966)(14.389)
Sign test0.8311.706***2.622***0.9711.771***1.791***1.542***
[p-value][0.1213][0.000][0.000][0.782][0.000][0.000][0.000]
Number of observations3045795184715821872641

This table shows the differences between buy-and-hold returns on a senator’s investment and the return of stocks the senator most recently sold if that sale happened within a week of the purchase. For each hold period, the first set of rows tests whether the difference between two returns is different from zero, while the second set of rows contains the results of the sign tests (also known as the median tests). For the sign test statistics, the ratio of positive/negative returns is reported along with statistical significance. The first 2years (2012 and 2013) have very few observations and have been omitted

***, **, and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively

Therefore, positive and significant returns would suggest that stocks that senators purchase perform better than those they just sold. We conduct two tests for mean values (t-tests) and median values (sign tests) to examine this. For the mean value tests, the t tests show that returns are higher after the purchases in general (except in 2014), and the effect increases with the longer holding periods. The median tests (sign tests) also present similar patterns. Consequently, we conclude that the primary reason for selling stocks is to secure profits and reserve liquidity for the next investments. That is, sale transactions may not be driven by negative stock information. We leave a more rigorous analysis of sale transactions for future research.

Summary and Conclusions

This paper suggests that political insider trading is unethical as it appears to expropriate other stakeholders’ expenses by exploiting information advantages gained through political position or connection (Bhattacharya & Daouk, 2002; Christensen et al., 2017; Gao & Huang, 2016). Its unethical nature is mainly due to conflict of interest and could raise social distrust.

We analyze electronic filings of stock trades made by senators in compliance with the STOCK Act to test whether politicians and their networks (i.e., staff, lobbyists, other- home state- legislators, and others) use political insider information in their investment decisions. First, we confirm politically informed trading by employing a buy-and-hold return analysis for stocks purchased by senators, a departure from the synthetic portfolio analysis used in prior studies. Moreover, we propose a modification of the abnormal idiosyncratic volatility (AIV), initially introduced by Yang et al. (2020), to measure the extent of information risk associated with periods around politicians’ trades. This approach allows us to capture possible (mis)use of inside political information for a much broader set of political actors, who may possess the same information as the senators in our sample but are not required to file reports on their stock trades. Thus, using the AIV measure is a noble method in that we are able to estimate the degree of politicians’ information asymmetry and test the validity of the social contract theory.

We show that information asymmetry associated with stocks traded by senators is, on average, relatively high (3.6%) and driven by the senator’s access to legislative information acquired by being an effective legislator or member of an important committee. The results suggest that the social contract theory is not supported by the results in our information asymmetry tests. In addition, our analysis confirms that information risk is elevated (attenuated) on days when there is a lot of legislative (lobbyist) activity. Lastly, we show that investing in the stock of a company headquartered in the senator’s state can yield high and significant returns, especially for more extended holding periods. Moreover, these trades are associated with significantly lower levels of AIV, suggesting that perhaps senators refrain from sharing value-relevant information with a broader set of associates.

Overall, our results showing high AIV around politicians’ trades support the view that senators’ use of inside political information represents only the tip of the iceberg. Many more legislators, politicians, and selected market participants have access to the same information but do not file their returns. We also believe that our results could shed more light on the puzzle of observed negative AIV values associated with some earnings announcements. If we purge periods surrounding politicians’ trades, obtaining a cleaner measure of AIV around corporate information events such as earnings announcements might be possible. Finally, our evidence refutes the social contract theory’s view of political insider trading. It suggests that there needs to be further discussion and deliberation leading to legislation further improving the STOCK Act.

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the section editor, Greg Shailer, two anonymous referees, Stephen Ferris, Randall Filer, Jan Hanousek, Svatopluk Kapounek, and seminar participants at the University of South Florida, 2020International Conference on Mathematical Methods in Economics, and2020 Conference of the Czech Economic Societyfor many valuable comments and suggestionsthat significantly improved earlier versions of this paper. However, the opinions expressed in this article are the authors’ own and do not reflect the view of the affiliated institutions.

Internet Appendix

See Fig. A.1.

See Tables (https://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html)11,11, scaling12,12, respectively.13,13, 1114,14, respectively1515.

Table 11

Detailed descriptions of the variables

VariablesDescriptions
Dependent variables
AIVAIV is calculated as the difference between annualized idiosyncratic volatility in the time window around the transactions and the rest of the year. The time window is 5days for each transaction 2days before, the transaction day, and 2days after. Data sources: CRSP and Compustat
AIVFIt is defined identically as AIV with a different time window, where the 5days include the transaction day and the following 4days. Data sources: CRSP and Compustat
AIVLIt is defined identically as AIV with a different time window, where the 5days include 4days before the transaction and the transaction day. Data sources: CRSP and Compustat
AIVEIt is defined as in Yang et al. (2020). It is calculated as the difference between annualized idiosyncratic volatility between the 5-day periods surrounding earnings announcements and the rest of the year. Data sources: CRSP and Compustat
Excess market returnsIt is defined as the difference between stock return and the S&P500 index return over the specified period. Data sources: CRSP
Senator tenure
0–4A dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator’s tenure in the specified year is between 0 and 4, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: Various sources including https://www.senate.gov/
5–13A dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator’s tenure in the specified year is between 5 and 13, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: Various sources including https://www.senate.gov/
14–35A dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator’s tenure in the specified year is between 14 and 35, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: Various sources including https://www.senate.gov/
Age category
41–50A dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator’s age in the specified year is between 41 and 50, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: Various sources including https://www.senate.gov/
51–60A dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator’s age in the specified year is between 51 and 60, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: Various sources including https://www.senate.gov/
60–65A dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator’s age in the specified year is between 60 and 65, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: Various sources including https://www.senate.gov/
 > 65A dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator’s age in the specified year is greater than 65, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: Various sources including https://www.senate.gov/
Account type
SelfA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the trade occurred on the senator’s own account, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: United States Senate Financial disclosures (https://efdsearch.senate.gov/)
ChildA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the trade occurred on the senator’s children account, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: United States Senate Financial disclosures (https://efdsearch.senate.gov/)
JointA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the trade occurred on the senator’s joint account with their spouse, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: United States Senate Financial disclosures (https://efdsearch.senate.gov/)
SpouseA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the trade occurred on the senator’s spouse account, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: United States Senate Financial disclosures (https://efdsearch.senate.gov/)
Other characteristics
FemaleA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator is female, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: Various sources including https://www.senate.gov/
DilutedWe define a transaction as diluted if either a) the senator has made a transaction with the same security on the same day, or b) he has traded the same security in immediate subsequent trading days. Data sources: United States Senate Financial disclosures (https://efdsearch.senate.gov/)
Home biasA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the firm has headquarters in the state of the senator, and 0 otherwise. Data sources: Compustat, Bill McDonald’s site (https://www3.nd.edu/~mcdonald/), and https://www.senate.gov/
Legislative control variables
Legislative effectiveness score (LES)The legislative effectiveness score is a measure of the legislative proficiency of each politician. Data sources: https://thelawmakers.org/
Finance CommitteeA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator is part of the Finance Committee. Data sources: Stewart (2012)
Appropriations CommitteeA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator is part of the Appropriations Committee. Data sources: Stewart (2012)
Rules and Administration CommitteeA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator is part of the Rules and Administration Committee. Data sources: Stewart (2012)
Armed Services CommitteeA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator is part of the Armed Services Committee. Data sources: Stewaof the12)
Foreign RelationsA dummy variable that is equal to 1 if the senator is part oft he Foreign Relations Committee. Data sources: Stewart (2012)
Number of billsThe number of bills that were introduced on the day of the trade with at least one lobbyist. The number is reported in hundreds. Data sources: OpenSecrets
Number of lobbyistsThe total number of lobbyists that are lobbying for laws introduced on the day of the trade. The number is reported in thousands. Data sources: OpenSecrets
Firm control variables
Past profitabilityGroup of variables Rm-1,Rm-3,m-2,Rm-6,m-4, and Rm-12,m-6, which stand for return over the last month, month 3 to 2, 6 to 4, and 12 to 6, respectively, as defined in Brennan et al. (2012). Data sources: CRSP
IlliquidityDefined as a sum of absolute values of daily returns divided by daily volume for the year, multiplied by 10^6. Defined by Amihud (2002). Data sources: CRSP
Firm sizeDefined as the natural logarithm of the market value of equity. Data sources: CRSP and Compustat
Book-to-market ratioDefined as book equity divided by market equity. Data sources: CRSP and Compustat
BetaCalculated using Fama–French 3 factor model using the past 6months of data. Data sources: CRSP and Kenneth French’s site (https://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html)

Table 12

Distribution of senators’ trades by security type and year

Type of account/transactionDirection of tradeYear of the recorded transaction
20122013201420152016201720182019Total
By account type
ChildBuy0.0%0.0%44.9%12.2%27.6%12.2%2.0%1.0%98
Sale0.0%0.0%27.1%21.4%21.4%12.9%10.0%7.1%70
JointBuy0.0%0.0%3.5%29.5%20.5%18.1%16.2%12.2%1784
Sale0.0%0.1%3.8%34.2%14.7%14.9%18.8%13.6%1893
SelfBuy0.0%0.1%18.3%14.2%18.7%19.4%16.5%12.8%717
Sale0.0%0.4%13.9%17.0%13.0%20.4%21.3%13.9%553
SpouseBuy0.2%0.7%15.1%11.0%12.4%20.9%28.8%10.8%1659
Sale0.2%0.2%27.8%8.7%10.9%19.1%23.0%10.1%1290
Non-diluted transactions vs. diluted transactions
Non-Diluted TransactionsBuy0.1%0.6%11.0%13.4%15.0%24.5%19.3%16.1%2304
Sale0.1%0.3%11.1%17.3%10.6%22.2%21.5%17.0%2099
Diluted TransactionsBuy0.0%0.0%12.0%26.3%19.9%13.2%22.6%6.1%1954
Sale0.0%0.0%17.2%29.6%16.6%10.8%19.1%6.6%1707
TotalBuy0.1%0.3%11.5%19.3%17.2%19.3%20.8%11.5%4258
Sale0.1%0.2%13.8%22.8%13.3%17.1%20.4%12.3%3806

This table reports the distribution of each security and direction of trade by year (row percentages). The last column contains the total number of transactions over the entire period and represents a hundred percent base for scaling

Table 13

Comparison of different measures of the AIV constructed on a 7-day computation window

Variables201420152016201720182019Total mean
Alternative AIV measures
AIV − 8.6%***6.7%***12.7%*** − 2.6%**8.4%***3.0%*4.0%***
AIVF − 9.9%***4.3%***6.4%*** − 7.7%***6.0%*** − 3.8%**0.2%
AIVL − 8.5%***6.8%***5.8%*** − 5.2%***6.8%***5.7%***2.4%***
AIVE − 1.30% − 3.30%***4.00%*** − 4.00%***1.00% − 2.10%** − 0.90%**
Alternative information asymmetry measures
Spread15.57***19.78***29.03***17.24***26.84***20.13***21.89***
Abnormal volume1.06***1.12***2.49***0.89***1.323***1.55***1.38***
Abnormal turnover0.952.21*** − 0.291.09***1.65***1.91***1.29***
Observations84115211082123213526936728

This table compares the mean of different measures of Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility (AIV) and alternative information asymmetry measures. For AIVF, the event window includes the trading day and six following days. For AIVL, the event window includes the trading day and six preceding days. AIVE is computed around the firm’s announcement of earnings, following the methodology of Yang et al. (2020). Spread is computed as (asking price–bidding price)/traded price, which is multiplied by the number of trades. Abnormal volume is trading volume (in millions) in the 7-day window surrounding the politician’s trade minus trading volume in the rest of the year. Abnormal turnover is the difference in turnover (= trading volume/shares outstanding) between the 7-day window and the rest of the year. The first 2years (2012 and 2013) are omitted due to very few observations

***, **, and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively.

Table 14

Additional summary statistics

VariableNMeanSta. devP25MedianP75
Firm characteristics
Firm size623510.3011.7448.97910.42411.702
Book-to-Market ratio61830.3950.4020.1720.3100.544
Illiquidity69630.0851.0070.0010.0030.008
Past profitability
Rm-168660.2719.797 − 4.2350.6005.284
Rm-3,m-268420.72412.181 − 5.2771.0856.915
Rm-6,m-468122.04414.530 − 4.7143.0749.885
Rm-12,m-667664.85719.235 − 4.5405.41015.237
Betas
Beta—1year67551.0210.3620.8121.0091.208
Beta—6months68111.0230.4080.7781.0061.240
Other characteristics
Home bias63490.0450.2080.0000.0000.000
Legislative variables
Legislative effectiveness score (LES)71400.7640.6060.2610.5231.012
Finance Committee71330.1530.3600.0000.0000.000
Appropriations Committee71330.2620.4400.0000.0001.000
Rules and Administration Committee71330.1300.3360.0000.0000.000
Armed Services Committee71330.2870.4530.0000.0001.000
Foreign Relations Committee71330.2050.4040.0000.0000.000
Number of bills71660.1620.2100.0000.1000.240
Number of lobbyists71660.3610.8160.0000.0330.286

For a detailed description of variables, see Table Table1111

Table 15

Regression of AIV using weighted OLS

Dependent variable = AIV
(1)(2)(3)
All transactionsAll transactionsStock purchases
Senator tenurea
Tenure 0–40.160***0.136**
(0.049)(0.056)
Tenure 5–130.0840.058
(0.074)(0.082)
Age categoryb
Age 41–50 − 0.378*** − 0.270*** − 0.137
(0.113)(0.101)(0.124)
Age 51–60 − 0.192*** − 0.085* − 0.177*
(0.061)(0.049)(0.094)
Age 60–65 − 0.132*** − 0.077* − 0.060
(0.049)(0.043)(0.068)
Account typec
Child − 0.031 − 0.030 − 0.063
(0.053)(0.053)(0.059)
Joint0.0080.0530.031
(0.039)(0.037)(0.053)
Spouse − 0.0260.0030.002
(0.053)(0.048)(0.067)
Other characteristics
Female − 0.046 − 0.071 − 0.135
(0.056)(0.054)(0.097)
Diluted − 0.013 − 0.010 − 0.013
(0.023)(0.023)(0.029)
Home bias − 0.142** − 0.128** − 0.259***
(0.057)(0.056)(0.069)
Legislative variables
Legislative effectiveness score (LES)0.0210.011 − 0.019
(0.031)(0.030)(0.043)
Finance Committee0.107*0.0550.105
(0.059)(0.054)(0.120)
Appropriations Committee0.024 − 0.0030.098*
(0.048)(0.044)(0.054)
Rules and Administration Committee − 0.0170.043 − 0.016
(0.045)(0.042)(0.059)
Armed Services Committee − 0.0170.008 − 0.065
(0.065)(0.049)(0.108)
Foreign Relations Committee − 0.0880.014 − 0.097
(0.080)(0.069)(0.122)
Number of bills0.155**0.142**0.162**
(0.069)(0.068)(0.075)
Number of lobbyists − 0.060*** − 0.058*** − 0.065***
(0.018)(0.018)(0.020)
Industry-related variables
Industry concentration1.381***1.422***0.413
(0.413)(0.415)(0.567)
Weight of stock in the industry0.1600.1760.394**
(0.148)(0.148)(0.196)
Constant0.401*0.484**0.459
(0.240)(0.222)(0.356)
Firm control variablesYesYesYes
Industry and year fixed effectsYesYesYes
R-squared0.12810.12410.1796
Observation (N)528352832793

Abnormal Idiosyncratic Volatility (AIV) computed over the 5-day event window. The weights used are the inverse of the number of ATT days divided by the numbers of NAT in the AIV calculation. Firm control variables include Size (log(market value of equity)), Book to Market, Illiquidity, past profitability, and market beta (12months). Reported are robust standard errors in parentheses

ais for senator tenure, where the base category is Tenure 14–35

bis for the age group, where the base category is Age > 65

cis for the account type, where the base category is Self

***, **, and * denote statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10%, respectively

Funding

This study was not funded by any grant.

Declarations

Conflict of Interest

All authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Ethical Approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Footnotes

1There is a plethora of popular press articles on politicians’ trading occurring prior to major news announcements. Some examples include the recent covid-19 onset and related lockdowns (e.g., see https://www.thedailybeast.com/sen-kelly-loeffler-dumped-millions-in-stock-after-coronavirus-briefing; https://www.ajc.com/news/state--regional-govt--politics/david-perdue-stock-trading-saw-uptick-coronavirus-took-hold/MRWmzwXeHgxi6IcmBbPgaN/; https://www.businessinsider.com/coronavirus-david-perdue-bought-stock-company-producing-ppe-after-briefing-2020-4; https://www.cnbc.com/2020/03/20/coronavirus-gop-sen-hoeven-bought-up-to-250000-in-health-fund-after-briefing.html; https://www.opensecrets.org/news/2020/03/burr-unloaded-stocks-before-coronavirus/), failed drug trials (e.g., https://nypost.com/2018/08/08/gop-congressman-busted-for-insider-trading/), the invasion of Ukraine by Russia (https://finance.yahoo.com/news/10-stocks-us-politicians-bought-164447897.html), or upcoming Obama Care legislation (https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB10001424052970204844504577100260349084878).

2Some studies show that investments by members of Congress outperform the market (Gao and Huang 2016; Jeng et al., 2003; Ziobrowski et al., 2004), presumably due to their significant informational advantage (Gao and Huang 2016; Ziobrowski et al., 2004). On the other hand, others suggest that stocks purchased by senators, on average, underperform the market (Belmont et al., 2020; Eggers and Hainmueller 2013). For instance, using portfolio analysis, Ziobrowski et al. (2004) show that government insiders outperform the market by 10% per year on average. Christensen et al. (2017) find more profitability from the recommendation revisions issued by analysts who are employed at politically connected brokerage houses.

3Conflict of interest in different contexts is discussed in Jensen and Meckling (1976), Boller and Ward (1995), Stark (2003), Rawls (1971), and Blau et al. (2021), among many others.

4Such political connections shaped the 2008 financial crisis bailout (Duchin and Sosyura 2012) and politicians’ support for the Economic Emergency Stabilization Act (Hassan et al., 2019).

5In his 2011 testimony on the STOCK Act proposal, Robert Khuzami states that “[t]here is no reason why trading by Members of Congress or their staff members would be considered “exempt” from the federal securities laws, including the insider trading prohibitions, though the application of these principles to such trading, particularly in the case of Members of Congress, is without direct precedent and may present some unique issues.” See https://www.sec.gov/news/testimony/2011/ts120611rk.htm.

6As described in Christensen et al (2017) political information encompasses “information about many types of issues, such as prospective legislation, upcoming government actions (e.g., interest rate cuts, military strikes), failed negotiations with other countries, unfolding economic crises (e.g., Great Recession), etc.”.

7For example, a 2013 Washington Post article states: “An April 1 alert to stock traders that predicted the outcome of a key Medicare funding decision has gained intense legal and public scrutiny. But a series of events in Washington and on Wall Street in the weeks before the alert raises the possibility that information related to the government’s decision may have previously circulated and moved the market, according to a trail of e-mails and market data.” (ElBoghdady and Hamburger 2013).

8In our application, we focus on senators because past results indicate that senators tend to perform better than representatives (e.g., Kim 2013a). In general, senators are more experienced and powerful, and they are better able to obtain inside information.

9The theory of virtue ethics (Aristotle 1926; Klaw and Mayer 2021; Maclntyre 1984, 1988; Murphy 1999) might be a plausible alternative perspective to the social contract theory, but nevertheless less suitable for interpreting empirical results as it does not have an accurate prediction of abnormal returns or information asymmetry.

10There were more than 7000 legislators in 2012 that had access to political insider information and could still trade on it without any repercussions after the passing of the STOCK Act (Kim 2013c). Currently, congressional aides and staffers do not have to disclose their trading activities (Lawder and Cowan 2012).

11Our study is different from Belmont et al. (2020) in that we mainly examine whether information asymmetry (AIV) is related to politicians’ trading. We contend that return analysis may not be ideal to conclude whether senators are informed or not. Our findings imply that the mass of unfiled transactions using the same inside information remains undetected. Therefore, examining abnormal idiosyncratic volatility at the stock level is more appropriate than tracing a politician’s investment performance only.

12In the context of corporate insiders, possible information trading can also be detected using the Easley and O’hara (1987) measure of the probability of information-driven trading (PIN). The various modifications of this technique, using a sequence of buy and sell signals, have become a benchmark and are frequently used (Hasbrouck 1991; Brennan and Subrahmanyam 1996; Easley et al., 2001; Aktas et al., 2008; Collin‐Dufresne and Fos 2015).

13We provide detailed descriptions of the variables including data sources in the internet appendix (Table 11).

14We describe the distribution and magnitude of diluted trades in the data section.

15We find 374 paper-based transactions for the sample period (2014 to 2019) that we use to analyze AIV and buy-and-hold abnormal returns. We find that our results are qualitatively similar even after adding these paper transactions to the sample.

16By the same token, we do not compare our results with some existing data fragments before the enactment of the STOCK Act.

17Though it may be hard to take advantage of insider information in a stock market since it requires more financial knowledge, it can be much easier in the bonds market. This may be why bonds are the second most traded category after stocks. This paper will not examine the issue more closely, but the problem warrants closer examination.

18This pattern seems to imply that senators’ decisions to sell are less informative, perhaps because of behavioral bias, such as the disposition effect. Another potential explanation for the negative returns in 2015 and 2018 is that senators were more focused on protecting their wealth when a regime shift in the upcoming election became more likely. This could be further supported by a different pattern for municipal and corporate bonds.

19Results are available in the internet appendix (Table 13).

20The negligible role of non-political information is also visible from the comparison of the AIV associated with the political trades and with the earning announcements. For the interest of the space, we do not present repeated tests and tables here. All results are available upon request.

21Duarte and Young (2009) argue that it is PIN’s liquidity component, rather than its information risk component, that is priced. In addition, Mohanram and Rajgopal (2009) and Lai et al. (2014) question the robustness of PIN’s return predictability in extended samples. Finally, PIN estimation has become increasingly challenging due to the ever-growing number of trades and high-frequency algorithmic trading (see Kim and Stoll 2014; Brogaard et al., 2019; Duarte et al., 2020).

22The methodology along with the data can be found at https://thelawmakers.org/.

23We also examine two interacted terms (AIV*Number of bills and AIV*Number of lobbyists) and find significantly positive effects for longer period excess returns (1month to 3months). This evidence implies that the actual effect of legislative/lobbying activity made via information asymmetry may not be properly captured in a short period (< 1month).

24If the senator sold multiple stocks on the same day, we take their average return.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Contributor Information

Jan Hanousek, Jr, Email: ude.fsu@kesuonahnaj.

Hoje Jo, Email: ude.ucs@ojh.

Christos Pantzalis, Email: ude.fsu@laztnapc.

Jung Chul Park, Email: ude.fsu@5krapj.

References

  • Aktas N, De Bodt E, Van Oppens H. Legal insider trading and market efficiency. Journal of Banking and Finance. 2008;32(7):1379–1392. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2007.11.003. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Ali U, Hirshleifer D. Opportunism as a firm and managerial trait: Predicting insider trading profits and misconduct. Journal of Financial Economics. 2017;126:490–515. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2017.09.002. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Amihud Y. Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-section and time-series effects. Journal of Financial Markets. 2002;5:31–56. doi:10.1016/S1386-4181(01)00024-6. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Aristotle . Nicomachean ethics (trans: Loeb Classical Library) Harvard University Press; 1926. [Google Scholar]
  • Armstrong CS, Core JE, Taylor DJ, Verrecchia RE. When does information asymmetry affect the cost of capital? Journal of Accounting Research. 2011;49(1):1–40. doi:10.1111/j.1475-679X.2010.00391.x. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Bainbridge SM. Introduction. In: Manne HG, editor. The collected works of Henry G Manne. Liberty Fund: Los Angeles; 2006. [Google Scholar]
  • Barbabella M, Cohen D, Kardon A, Molk P. Insider trading in congress the need for regulation. Journal of Business and Securities Law. 2009;199(9):199–237. [Google Scholar]
  • Barry B. Why social justice matters? Polity Press; 2005. [Google Scholar]
  • Belmont W, Sacerdote B, Van Hoek I. Relief rally: Senators as f*ckless as the rest of us at stock picking. National Bureau of Economic Research; 2020. [Google Scholar]
  • Berkman H, Koch P, Westerholm P. Informed trading through the accounts of children. Journal of Finance. 2014;69:363–404. doi:10.1111/jofi.12043. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Bhattacharya U, Daouk H. The world price of insider trading. Journal of Finance. 2002;57:75–108. doi:10.1111/1540-6261.00416. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Blau B, Griffith T, Whitby R. On the ethics of “non-corporate” insider trading. Journal of Business Ethics. 2022;177:79–93. doi:10.1007/s10551-021-04739-x. [PMC free article] [PubMed] [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Boller, G., & Ward, J. (1995). Taking stock in Congress by Joy Ward, Mother Jones, September/October Issue
  • Brennan MJ, Chordia T, Subrahmanyam A, Tong Q. Sell-order liquidity and the cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics. 2012;105:523–541. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.04.006. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Brennan MJ, Subrahmanyam A. Market microstructure and asset pricing: On the compensation for illiquidity in stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics. 1996;41(3):441–464. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(95)00870-K. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Brogaard J, Hendershott T, Riordan R. Price discovery without trading: Evidence from limit orders. Journal of Finance. 2019;74:1621–1658. doi:10.1111/jofi.12769. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Brudney V. Insiders, outsiders, and informational advantages under the federal securities laws. Harvard Law Review. 1979;93:322–376. doi:10.2307/1340381. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Christensen DM, Mikhail MB, Walther BR, Wellman LA. From K Street to Wall Street: Political connections and stock recommendations. Accounting Review. 2017;92(3):87–112. doi:10.2308/accr-51550. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Collin-Dufresne P, Fos V. Do prices reveal the presence of informed trading? Journal of Finance. 2015;70(4):1555–1582. doi:10.1111/jofi.12260. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Duarte J, Hu L, Young L. A Comparison of some structural models of private information arrival. Journal of Financial Economics. 2020;135(3):795–815. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2019.08.005. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Duarte J, Young L. Why is PIN priced? Journal of Financial Economics. 2009;91:119–138. [Google Scholar]
  • Duchin R, Sosyura D. The politics of government investment. Journal of Financial Economics. 2012;106:24–48. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.04.009. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Dunfee T, Donaldson T. Contractarian business ethics: Current status and next steps. Business Ethics Quarterly. 1995;5(2):173–186. doi:10.2307/3857352. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Easley D, Kiefer N, O’Hara M, Paperman JB. Liquidity, information, and infrequently traded stocks. Journal of Finance. 1996;51:1405–1436. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1996.tb04074.x. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Easley D, López de Prado M, O’Hara M. Flow toxicity and liquidity in a high frequency world. Review of Financial Studies. 2012;25:1457–1493. doi:10.1093/rfs/hhs053. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Easley D, O’Hara M. Price, trade size, and information in securities markets. Journal of Financial Economics. 1987;19:69–90. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(87)90029-8. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Easley D, O’Hara M, Saar G. How stock splits affect trading: A microstructure approach. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. 2001;36:25–51. doi:10.2307/2676196. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Eggers AC, Hainmueller J. Capitol losses: The mediocre performance of Congressional stock portfolios. Journal of Politics. 2013;75:535–551. doi:10.1017/S0022381613000194. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Eggers AC, Hainmueller J. Political capital: Corporate connections and stock investments in the U.S. congress, 2004–2008. Quarterly Journal of Political Science. 2014;9(2):169–202. doi:10.1561/100.00013077. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • ElBoghdady, D., & Hamburger, T. (2013, May 3). Timing of political intelligence probed. The Washington Post.
  • Fama EF, French KR. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics. 1993;33:3–56. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(93)90023-5. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Fama EF, French KR. Industry costs of equity. Journal of Financial Economics. 1997;43(2):153–193. doi:10.1016/S0304-405X(96)00896-3. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Fandos, N. (2020, June 15). To gain public’s trust, should memebers of Congress stop trading stock? NY Times. Retrieved from https://www.nytimes.com/2020/06/15/us/politics/congress-trading-stock-loeffler-burr.html.
  • Ferguson T, Voth HJ. Betting on Hitler—the value of political connections in Nazi Germany. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2008;123(1):101–137. doi:10.1162/qjec.2008.123.1.101. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Fowler JH. Connecting the congress: A study of cosponsorship networks. Political Analysis. 2006;14:456–487. doi:10.1093/pan/mpl002. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Fowler JH. Legislative cosponsorship networks in the U.S. house and senate. Social Networks. 2006;28(4):454–465. doi:10.1016/j.socnet.2005.11.003. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Gao M, Huang J. Capitalizing on Capitol Hill: Informed trading by hedge fund managers. Journal of Financial Economics. 2016;121(3):521–545. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2015.11.001. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Gilson R, Kraakman R. The mechanisms of market efficiency. Virginia Law Review. 1984;70:549–644. doi:10.2307/1073080. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Hasbrouck J. Measuring the information content of stock trades. Journal of Finance. 1991;46(1):179–207. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1991.tb03749.x. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Hassan TA, Hollander S, Van Lent L, Tahoun A. Firm-level political risk: Measurement and effects. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2019;134:2135–2202. doi:10.1093/qje/qjz021. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Hobbes, T. (1651). Leviathan. C. B. Macpherson (Ed.). London: Penguin Books (1985).
  • Huang, R., & Xuan, Y. (2019). ‘Trading’ political favors: Evidence from the impact of the STOCK act. Available at SSRN 2765876.
  • Jeng LA, Metrick A, Zeckhauser R. Estimating the returns to insider trading: A performance-evaluation perspective. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2003;85:453–471. doi:10.1162/003465303765299936. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Jensen MC, Meckling WH. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics. 1976;3(4):305–360. doi:10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Jerke B. Cashing in on Capitol Hill: Insider trading and the use of political intelligence for profit. University of Pennsylvania Law Review. 2010;158(5):1451–1521. [Google Scholar]
  • Karadas S. Family ties and informed trading: Evidence from Capitol Hill. Journal of Economics and Finance. 2018;42:211–248. doi:10.1007/s12197-017-9384-z. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Kim, S.H. (2013c). What governmental insider trading teaches us about corporate insider trading. In Research handbook on insider trading. Edward Elgar Publishing.
  • Kim SH. Insider trading as private corruption. UCLA Law Review. 2013;61:928. [Google Scholar]
  • Kim SH. The last temptation of Congress: Legislator insider trading and the fiduciary norm against corruption. Cornell Law Review. 2013;98:845. [Google Scholar]
  • Kim ST, Stall HR. Are trading imballances indicative of private information? Journal of Financial Markets. 2014;20:151–174. doi:10.1016/j.finmar.2014.03.003. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Klaw B, Mayer D. Ethics, markets, and the legalization of insider trading. Journal of Business Ethics. 2021;168:55–70. doi:10.1007/s10551-019-04238-0. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Kocieniewski, D., & Farrell, G. (2020). Senators’ stock sales likely to prompt ethics, voter scrutiny. Retrieved from https://www.bloombergquint.com/onweb/senators-stock-sales-likely-to-prompt-ethics-voter-scrutiny. 2020 Bloomberg L.P. Copyright © BloombergQuint
  • Korab-Karpowicz, W.J. (2010). Political realism in international relations. Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, Zalta, E.N. (ed.).
  • Kyle AS. Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica. 1985;53:1315–1335. doi:10.2307/1913210. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Lai S, Ng L, Zhang B. Does PIN affect equity prices around the world? Journal of Financial Economics. 2014;114:178–195. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.06.005. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Lawder, D., & Cowan, R. (2012). Congress quietly repeals plan for Internet financial disclosures. In Reuters. Thomson Reuters. Retrieved from https://www.reuters.com/article/net-us-usa-congress-security-idUSBRE93B0ZJ20130412.
  • Levinthal, D. (October 21, 2021). 43 members of Congress have violated a law designed to stop insider trading and prevent conflicts-of-interest. Insider.
  • Lin J-C, Rozeff MS. The speed of adjustment of prices to private information: Empirical tests. Journal of Financial Research. 1995;18:143–156. doi:10.1111/j.1475-6803.1995.tb00558.x. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Locke J. Two treatises of government and a letter concerning toleration. Yale University Press; 2003. [Google Scholar]
  • Maclntyre A. After virtue. 2. University of Notre Dame Press; 1984. [Google Scholar]
  • Maclntyre A. Whose justice? Which rationality? University of Notre Dame Press; 1988. [Google Scholar]
  • Manne HG. Insider trading and the stock market. Free; 1966. [Google Scholar]
  • Mendeluk Paulina. Public sphere and the political morality in a liberal democracy. Analele Universit ăţii din Qradea, Seria Geografie. 2018 doi:10.30892/auog.24.ISSN1221-1273. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Mesiya S. Failure of the STOCK Act and the future of Congressional insider trader reform. American Criminal Law Review. 2021;58:92–100. [Google Scholar]
  • Meulbroek LK. An empirical analysis of insider trading. Journal of Finance. 1992;47:1661–1699. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6261.1992.tb04679.x. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Mohanram P, Rajgopal S. Is PIN priced risk? Journal of Accounting and Economics. 2009;47:226–243. doi:10.1016/j.jacceco.2008.10.001. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Moore J. What is really unethical about insider trading? Journal of Business Ethics. 1990;9(3):171–182. doi:10.1007/BF00382642. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Murphy P. Character and virtue ethics in international marketing: An agenda for managers, researchers and educators. Journal of Business Ethics. 1999;18(1):107–124. doi:10.1023/A:1006072413165. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Odean T. Do investors trade too much? American Economic Review. 1999;89:1279–1298. doi:10.1257/aer.89.5.1279. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Rawls J. A theory of justice. Harvard University Press; 1971. [Google Scholar]
  • Rousseau, J. (1987). The basic political writings. (Trans. Donald A. Cress). Hackett Publishing Company.
  • Salbu S. Insider trading and the social contract. Business Ethics Quarterly. 1995;5(2):313–338. doi:10.2307/3857359. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Snedecor GW, Cochran WG. Statistical methods. 8. Ames: Iowa State Univ. Press Iowa; 1989. pp. 71–82. [Google Scholar]
  • Stark A. Conflict of interest in American public life. Harvard University Press; 2003. [Google Scholar]
  • Stewart III, C. (2012). The value of committee assignments in Congress since 1994. Working paper, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
  • Tahoun A. The role of stock ownership by U.S. members of Congress on the market for political favors. Journal of Financial Economics. 2014;111:86–110. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.10.008. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Tramontano, K. (2017, March 7). America is failing workers left behind by the new economy. Washington Monthly.
  • Walzer M. Just and unjust wars: A moral argument with historical illustrations. Basic Books; 1977. pp. 4–13. [Google Scholar]
  • Werhane PH. The ethics of insider trading. Journal of Business Ethics. 1989;8(11):841–845. doi:10.1007/BF00384525. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Werhane PH. The indefensibility of insider trading. Journal of Business Ethics. 1991;10(9):729–731. doi:10.1007/BF00705879. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Yang YC, Zhang B, Zhang C. Is information risk priced? Evidence from abnormal idiosyncratic volatility. Journal of Financial Economics. 2020;135:528–554. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2019.06.013. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Zingales L. A capitalism for the people: Recapturing the lost genius of American prosperity. Basic Books; 2012. [Google Scholar]
  • Ziobrowski AJ, Cheng P, Boyd JW, Ziobrowski BJ. Abnormal returns from the common stock investments of the U.S. Senate. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis. 2004;39:661–676. doi:10.1017/S0022109000003161. [CrossRef] [Google Scholar]
  • Ziolkowski, C. (2020). Senators dumped stocks amid the coronavirus crisis. Here’s what we know about Congress and financial self-interest. In: Washington Post. Washington Post, New York.

Articles from Journal of Business Ethics are provided here courtesy of Nature Publishing Group

A Dilemma of Self-interest vs. Ethical Responsibilities in Political Insider Trading (2024)

FAQs

What is the ethical dilemma insider trading? ›

Insider trading in financial markets presents various ethical issues, including conflicting rights, differing cultural norms, and inequalities across market participants.

Is insider trading a conflict of interest? ›

Any information of this type used for personal gain by an employee is a huge conflict of interest, at least in the United States. The financial industry constantly grapples with this type of conflict of interest in the form of insider trading.

What is unethical about insider trading? ›

Insider trading causes regular people to have a pessimistic view of the market due because of the unfair advantage insider trading have by using non-public material information. As a result, ordinary people are less likely to participate in the market, which decreases overall market liquidity and efficiency.

What is the ethical theory of insider trading? ›

The classical theory of insider trading requires that the individual trading on inside information have a fiduciary duty to disclose the information.

What are 3 ethical dilemmas a business might face? ›

Racial discrimination, sexual harassment, wage inequality – are all costly ethical issues that employers and employees encounter on a daily basis across the country.

What is an example of ethical trading? ›

Ethical trade and suppliers

For example, you might try to use local suppliers as much as possible. This helps you to support your local community and reduces the environmental impact of your sourcing, logistics and distribution practices. When choosing suppliers, you should also examine their: employment practices.

What is insider trading in politics? ›

The insider trading law has progressed from an expansive approach under which corporate outsiders, including politicians, are permitted to trade on non-public information provided such trading does not breach a fiduciary duty.

What is a conflict of interest in ethics? ›

A conflict of interest occurs when an individual's personal interests – family, friendships, financial, or social factors – could compromise his or her judgment, decisions, or actions in the workplace. Government agencies take conflicts of interest so seriously that they are regulated.

What is conflict of interest in trading? ›

Conflict of interest is a situation where there is a difference between the economic interests of the Company and the personal economic interests of shareholders, the Board of Commissioners and the Board of Directors, and employees of the Company.

What is the biggest insider trading scandal? ›

Raj Rajaratnam and the Galleon Mess

They snagged non-public details about different companies to make money-spinning trades in their stocks before the info went public. The illegal scheme raked in over $60 million , making it the biggest hedge fund insider trading case in U.S. history back then.

What is the ethical code for insider trading? ›

CODE OF ETHICS & INSIDER TRADING

The rule sets forth a minimum set of requirements, such as prohibitions of the use of material non-public information for personal gain and reporting personal securities transactions.

Why is insider trading so hard to prove? ›

Insider trading is a type of market abuse when an advantageous trade is made based on material nonpublic information. The issue is there's not a specific law defining what insider trading is, which makes it difficult to prosecute cases as they arise.

What are the two main theories of insider trading? ›

Three theories of liability establish the prohibitions on insider trading law: (1) the classical or traditional theory, (2) misappropriation theory, and (3) tipper/tippee liability.

What are the ethical issues of insider research? ›

Role Conflict. One of the core ethical issues of insider research is role conflict. As a member of a social or professional group, the insider is expected to conduct themselves in accordance with the norms of the group.

Which of the following best describes why insider trading is said to be unethical? ›

Which of the following best describes why insider trading is said to be unethical? The theft of information gives the insider an unfair advantage in the organization and the markets.

What is the insider outsider dilemma? ›

"Getting in," the process of gaining, building, and maintaining trust with the group under study, is difficult for any researcher. Differences of ethnicity, age, and class between the researcher, who is considered an Outsider, and the Insiders, members of the group being studied, pose special problems.

What is the issue with insider trading? ›

Insider trading is buying or selling a publicly traded company's stock by someone with non-public, material information about that company. Non-public, material information is any information that could substantially impact an investor's decision to buy or sell a security that has not been made available to the public.

Top Articles
What To Do If Your Key Won't Turn In The Lock | Issues & Solutions
Internet overuse and addiction
Ret Paladin Phase 2 Bis Wotlk
Voorraad - Foodtrailers
St Als Elm Clinic
Oppenheimer & Co. Inc. Buys Shares of 798,472 AST SpaceMobile, Inc. (NASDAQ:ASTS)
Whiskeytown Camera
Craigslist Phoenix Cars By Owner Only
Strange World Showtimes Near Cmx Downtown At The Gardens 16
Koop hier ‘verloren pakketten’, een nieuwe Italiaanse zaak en dit wil je ook even weten - indebuurt Utrecht
Jenn Pellegrino Photos
Rachel Griffin Bikini
Trac Cbna
Army Oubs
Wgu Academy Phone Number
Icivics The Electoral Process Answer Key
Between Friends Comic Strip Today
Finding Safety Data Sheets
Water Temperature Robert Moses
Top 20 scariest Roblox games
Bolly2Tolly Maari 2
Craigslist Brandon Vt
The Fabelmans Showtimes Near Baton Rouge
Calvin Coolidge: Life in Brief | Miller Center
Evil Dead Rise - Everything You Need To Know
Unm Hsc Zoom
Blackstone Launchpad Ucf
Scioto Post News
Exploring The Whimsical World Of JellybeansBrains Only
#1 | Rottweiler Puppies For Sale In New York | Uptown
R Nba Fantasy
Anya Banerjee Feet
Conroe Isd Sign In
2007 Jaguar XK Low Miles for sale - Palm Desert, CA - craigslist
Trivago Anaheim California
Tableaux, mobilier et objets d'art
Natasha Tosini Bikini
Greatpeople.me Login Schedule
Mejores páginas para ver deportes gratis y online - VidaBytes
1990 cold case: Who killed Cheryl Henry and Andy Atkinson on Lovers Lane in west Houston?
Blippi Park Carlsbad
Diario Las Americas Rentas Hialeah
Bbwcumdreams
Craigslist Psl
Hampton Inn Corbin Ky Bed Bugs
Parks And Rec Fantasy Football Names
Black Adam Showtimes Near Cinemark Texarkana 14
Uncle Pete's Wheeling Wv Menu
Https://Eaxcis.allstate.com
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Ray Christiansen

Last Updated:

Views: 5907

Rating: 4.9 / 5 (69 voted)

Reviews: 84% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Ray Christiansen

Birthday: 1998-05-04

Address: Apt. 814 34339 Sauer Islands, Hirtheville, GA 02446-8771

Phone: +337636892828

Job: Lead Hospitality Designer

Hobby: Urban exploration, Tai chi, Lockpicking, Fashion, Gunsmithing, Pottery, Geocaching

Introduction: My name is Ray Christiansen, I am a fair, good, cute, gentle, vast, glamorous, excited person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.