Bank Runs - Econlib (2024)

Table of Contents
About the Author Further Reading

A run on a bank occurs when a large number of depositors, fearing that their bank will be unable to repay their deposits in full and on time, simultaneously try to withdraw their funds immediately. This may create a problem because banks keep only a small fraction of deposits on hand in cash; they lend out the majority of deposits to borrowers or use the funds to purchase other interest-bearing assets such as government securities. When a run comes, a bank must quickly increase its cash to meet depositors’ demands. It does so primarily by selling assets, often hastily and at fire-sale prices. As banks hold little capital and are highly leveraged, losses on these sales can drive a bank into insolvency.

The danger of bank runs has been frequently overstated. For one thing, a bank run is unlikely to cause insolvency. Suppose that depositors, worried about their bank’s solvency, start a run and switch their deposits to other banks. If their concerns about the bank’s solvency are unjustified, other banks in the same market area will generally gain from recycling funds they receive back to the bank experiencing the run. They would do this by making loans to the bank or by purchasing the bank’s assets at non-fire-sale prices. Thus, a run is highly unlikely to make a solvent bank insolvent.

Of course, if the depositors’ fears are justified and the bank is economically insolvent, other banks will be unlikely to throw good money after bad by recycling their funds to the insolvent bank. As a result, the bank cannot replenish its liquidity and will be forced into default. But the run would not have caused the insolvency; rather, the recognition of the existing insolvency caused the run.

A more serious potential problem is spillover to other banks. The likelihood of this happening depends on what the “running” depositors do with their funds. They have three choices:

1- They can redeposit the money in banks that they think are safe, known as direct redeposit.

2- If they perceive no bank to be safe, they can buy treasury securities in a “flight to quality.” But what do the sellers of the securities do? If they deposit the proceeds in banks they believe are safe, as is likely, this is an indirect redeposit.

3- If neither the depositors nor the sellers of the treasury securities believe that any bank is safe, they hold the funds as currency outside the banking system. A run on individual banks would then be transformed into a run on the banking system as a whole.

If the run is either type 1 or type 2, no great harm is done. The deposits and reserves are reshuffled among the banks, possibly including overseas banks, but do not leave the banking system. Temporary loan disruptions may occur because borrowers have to transfer from deposit-losing to deposit-gaining banks, and interest rates and exchange rates (see foreign exchange) may change. But these costs are not the calamities that people often associate with bank runs.

Higher costs could occur in a type 3 run, because currency (an important component of bank reserves) would be removed from the banking system. Banks operate on a fractional reserve basis, which means that they hold only a fraction of their deposits as reserves. When people try to convert their deposits into currency, the money supply shrinks, dampening economic activity in other sectors. In addition, almost all banks would sell assets to replenish their liquidity, but few banks would be buying. Losses would be large, and the number of bank failures would increase.

In practice, bank failures have been relatively infrequent. From the end of the Civil War through 1920 (after the Federal Reserve was established in 1913 but before the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation was formed in 1933), the bank failure rate was lower, on average, than that of nonbanking firms. The failure rate increased sharply in the 1920s and again between 1929 and 1933, when nearly 40 percent of U.S. banks failed. Yet, from 1875 through 1933, losses from failures averaged only 0.2 percent of total deposits in the banking system annually. Losses to depositors at failed banks averaged only a fraction of the annual losses suffered by bondholders of failed nonbanking firms.

A survey of all failures of national banks from 1865 through 1936 by J. F. T. O’Connor, comptroller of the currency from 1933 through 1938, concluded that runs were a contributing cause in less than 15 percent of the three thousand failures. The fact that the number of runs on individual banks was far greater than this means that most runs did not lead to failures.

The evidence suggests that most bank runs were then and are today type 1 or 2, and few were of the contagious type 3. Because a type 3 run—a run on the banking system—causes an outflow of currency, such a run can be identified by an increase in the ratio of currency to the money supply (most of the various measures of the money supply consist of currency in the hands of the public plus different types of bank deposits). Increases in this ratio have occurred in only four periods since the Civil War, and in only two—1893 and 1929–1933—did an unusually large number of banks fail. Thus, market forces and the banking system on its own successfully insulated runs on individual banks in most periods. Moreover, even in the 1893 and 1929–1933 incidents, the evidence is unclear whether the increase in bank failures caused the economic downturn or the economic downturn caused the bank failures. As a result of the introduction of deposit insurance in 1933, runs into currency are even less likely today. The threat of runs from perceived troubled large banks, which have sizable uninsured deposits, to perceived safe banks serves as a form of market discipline that may reduce the likelihood of runs on all banks by giving them an incentive to strengthen their financial positions.

About the Author

George G. Kaufman is the John F. Smith Professor of Finance and Economics at Loyola University in Chicago. He is also cochair of the Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee.

Further Reading

Allen, Franklin, and Douglas Gale. “Optimal Financial Crises.” Journal of Finance 53, no. 4 (1998): 1245–1284.

Benston, George J., Robert A. Eisenbeis, Paul M. Horvitz, Edward J. Kane, and George G. Kaufman. Perspectives on Safe and Sound Banking. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1986.

Carlstrom, Charles T. “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Bank Regulation.” Parts 1 and 2. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Commentary, February 1 and 15, 1988.

Diamond, Douglas W., and Philip H. Dybvig. “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance and Liquidity.” Journal of Political Economy 91, no. 3 (1983): 401–419.

Gorton, Gary. “Banking Panics and Business Cycles.” Oxford Economic Papers 40 (December 1988): 751–781.

Kaufman, George G. “Bank Runs: Causes, Benefits and Costs.” Cato Journal 2, no. 3 (1988): 559–588.

Kaufman, George G. “Banking Risk in Historical Perspective.” Research in Financial Services 1 (1989): 151–164.

Neuberger, Jonathan A. “Depositor Discipline and Bank Runs.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, weekly letter, April 12, 1991.

Schumaker, Liliana. “Bank Runs and Currency Runs in a System Without a Safety Net.” Journal of Monetary Economics 46, no. 1 (2000): 257–277.

Tallman, Ellis. “Some Unanswered Questions About Bank Panics.” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review, November/December 1988.

Bank Runs - Econlib (2024)
Top Articles
Ocean Cargo INCOTERMS and Insurance | Chubb
Bank of America To Partner With Ripple for ODL Services After XRP Lawsuit Finishes: Report - The Daily Hodl
11 beste sites voor Word-labelsjablonen (2024) [GRATIS]
My Arkansas Copa
Housing near Juneau, WI - craigslist
Froedtert Billing Phone Number
Black Gelato Strain Allbud
Jesse Mckinzie Auctioneer
Dark Souls 2 Soft Cap
Olivia Ponton On Pride, Her Collection With AE & Accidentally Coming Out On TikTok
Ave Bradley, Global SVP of design and creative director at Kimpton Hotels & Restaurants | Hospitality Interiors
Driving Directions To Atlanta
Valentina Gonzalez Leak
Current Time In Maryland
Mary Kay Lipstick Conversion Chart PDF Form - FormsPal
Walmart End Table Lamps
Brett Cooper Wikifeet
Everything you need to know about Costco Travel (and why I love it) - The Points Guy
Finalize Teams Yahoo Fantasy Football
The Ultimate Guide to Extras Casting: Everything You Need to Know - MyCastingFile
Www.dunkinbaskinrunsonyou.con
Slim Thug’s Wealth and Wellness: A Journey Beyond Music
Craigslist Roseburg Oregon Free Stuff
683 Job Calls
Rs3 Ushabti
Silky Jet Water Flosser
Craigslist Panama City Beach Fl Pets
Local Collector Buying Old Motorcycles Z1 KZ900 KZ 900 KZ1000 Kawasaki - wanted - by dealer - sale - craigslist
Dmv In Anoka
Skidware Project Mugetsu
Miller Plonka Obituaries
lol Did he score on me ?
24 Hour Drive Thru Car Wash Near Me
1475 Akron Way Forney Tx 75126
A Grade Ahead Reviews the Book vs. The Movie: Cloudy with a Chance of Meatballs - A Grade Ahead Blog
Craigslist Pets Huntsville Alabama
Paperless Employee/Kiewit Pay Statements
O'reilly's Palmyra Missouri
Chathuram Movie Download
Subdomain Finder
All Weapon Perks and Status Effects - Conan Exiles | Game...
Truck Works Dothan Alabama
Makes A Successful Catch Maybe Crossword Clue
White County
Alba Baptista Bikini, Ethnicity, Marriage, Wedding, Father, Shower, Nazi
Random Animal Hybrid Generator Wheel
Victoria Vesce Playboy
Canada Life Insurance Comparison Ivari Vs Sun Life
Whitney Wisconsin 2022
The top 10 takeaways from the Harris-Trump presidential debate
Fredatmcd.read.inkling.com
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Jamar Nader

Last Updated:

Views: 6136

Rating: 4.4 / 5 (75 voted)

Reviews: 82% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Jamar Nader

Birthday: 1995-02-28

Address: Apt. 536 6162 Reichel Greens, Port Zackaryside, CT 22682-9804

Phone: +9958384818317

Job: IT Representative

Hobby: Scrapbooking, Hiking, Hunting, Kite flying, Blacksmithing, Video gaming, Foraging

Introduction: My name is Jamar Nader, I am a fine, shiny, colorful, bright, nice, perfect, curious person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.